IEO logo
IEO Home

Independence

Goals & Instruments

Transparency

Work Program

Ongoing Projects

IEO Publications

Staffing

Terms of Reference

Origins of the IEO

Links to Related Sites


Independent Evaluation Office - Work Program

July, 2003
The IEO provides objective and independent evaluation on issues related to the IMF. The Office operates independently of IMF management and at arm's length from the IMF's Executive Board.

The Role of the IMF in Argentina, 1991-2002
Issues Paper/Terms of Reference for an Evaluation by the Independent Evaluation Office (IEO)

This document is available in Spanish (221 kb PDF file) - [Disclaimer: Reasonable efforts to ensure accuracy of these documents have been made; however, only the English version produced by the IEO is the authentic version]

Full text in PDF Format (199Kb)  

I. Introduction

II. Background

III. Issues for Evaluation

IV. The Methodology and Timeline of the Evaluation

Bibliography




The Role of the IMF in Argentina, 1991-2002
Draft Issues Paper for an Evaluation by the Independent Evaluation Office (IEO)

I. Introduction

Argentina was plunged into a devastating economic crisis in December 2001/January 2002, when a partial deposit freeze, a partial default on public debt, and an abandonment of the fixed exchange rate led to a collapse in output, high levels of unemployment, and political and social turmoil. These events have raised questions regarding the country's relationship with the IMF because they happened while its economic policies were under the close scrutiny of an IMF-supported program. Furthermore, the IMF had been almost continuously engaged in Argentina since 1991, when the "Convertibility Plan" fixed the Argentine peso at parity with the U.S. dollar in a currency board-like arrangement. While Argentina experienced strong growth and very low inflation for much of the 1990s, it fell into a deep recession in 1998 and, partly because of the strictures of the convertibility regime, became increasingly constrained in its ability to use standard macroeconomic policy tools to engineer a recovery. As the economy slowed and international investors became nervous, the country's already high external debt service burden grew to a point where the debt became unsustainable.

Until shortly before the crisis, the country had been widely praised for its achievements in stabilization, economic growth and market-oriented reforms under IMF-supported programs. During the decade preceding the crisis, there were four successive financing arrangements for Argentina and its balance of outstanding credit to the IMF rose sharply after 2000 (Figure 1).1 The IMF also provided extensive technical assistance (TA) during the period, dispatching some 50 missions between 1991 and 2002, mainly in the fiscal, monetary and banking areas.

While ultimate accountability for a member country's economic policy must rest with its national authorities, since the crisis, a number of observers have raised questions about the effectiveness and quality of financing and policy advice provided by the IMF. Some critics have argued that the IMF's main fault lay in providing too much financing without requiring sufficient policy adjustment, while others have alleged that the policies recommended by the IMF actually contributed to the crisis. In either case, the eventual collapse of the convertibility regime and the associated adverse economic and social consequences for the country have, rightly or wrongly, had a reputational cost for the IMF.

Figure 1

This evaluation will focus on the period from 1991 to early 2002, covering the time from the adoption of the convertibility regime to the immediate aftermath of its collapse.2 The evaluation will review the evolution of the IMF's advice and internal views on key areas of Argentina's economic policy, identify how the IMF came to certain decisions at critical junctures in its relationship with the country, and assess how reasonable the decisions were in light of information available at the time. The evaluation will also consider—with the benefit of hindsight—if better outcomes could have been achieved with a different set of decisions by the IMF. Since the decisions of the IMF could not have been independent of the decisions and actions of the national authorities, the evaluation will implicitly take positions on decisions of the authorities in some cases, particularly when considering ownership and implementation issues. However, the primary focus of the evaluation will be placed on drawing lessons for the IMF. In discussing the decision making process within the IMF, due attention will be paid to the respective roles played by IMF staff, management, the Executive Board and, to the extent possible, the major shareholder governments.

This version of the paper incorporates the many comments and suggestions on an earlier draft received from IMF staff, members of the Executive Board, external experts and visitors to the IEO's website. It is now being published on the website to invite inputs and comments on the set of issues the IEO intends to explore in the evaluation. Section II briefly surveys the key developments in Argentina's economy and economic policies during the period under consideration, and reviews some of the interpretations of these events that have been provided by academic and other observers. Section III discusses the principal issues that the IEO has identified as relevant for the evaluation. Finally, section IV describes the methodology and timeline of the evaluation.

II. Background

A. Economic Developments under the Convertibility Plan

Following a decade of high inflation and stagnant output, and several failed attempts to stabilize the economy, Argentina fell into hyperinflation in 1989. The Convertibility Plan, introduced in April 1991, was designed to stabilize the economy through drastic, and almost irreversible, measures. The plan was centered around the use of a currency board-like arrangement, in which the peso (set equal to 10,000 australes) was fixed at par with the U.S. dollar and autonomous money creation by the central bank was severely constrained. Significantly, it also included a broader agenda of market-oriented structural reforms to promote efficiency and productivity.

After the adoption of the Convertibility Plan, stabilization was achieved quickly and, with the aid of structural reforms, the economy grew at an average rate of 6 percent per year through 1997 (see Table 1 in the appendix for key economic indicators during 1991-2002). Although a few recessionary episodes were experienced, they were short lived and, except for the one that followed the Mexican crisis in early 1995, relatively mild. The Mexican crisis tested the resilience of the convertibility regime, as interest rates rose sharply, output fell substantially, and unemployment increased to over 18 percent. When a V-shaped recovery ensued, this was widely interpreted as evidence of its robustness and credibility.

The recession that began in the second half of 1998, however, turned out to be both prolonged and severe. It was triggered and then compounded by a series of adverse external shocks, particularly the Russian default and the LTCM crisis in August-September 1998 and the devaluation of the Brazilian real in January 1999. In contrast to most other emerging market economies at the time, the Argentine economy did not enjoy a rapid recovery. Instead, the sluggishness of GDP growth fueled concerns about the sustainability of public debt, concerns which eventually became self-fulfilling.

In late 2000, Argentina began to experience severely diminished access to capital markets, as reflected in a sharp and sustained rise in spreads on Argentine bonds over U.S. Treasuries (Figure 2). To this, the IMF responded by providing exceptional financial support. Uneven implementation of promised fiscal adjustment and reforms, a worsening global macroeconomic environment, and political instability, however, led to the complete loss of market access and intensified capital flight by the second quarter of 2001. A series of deposit runs began to have a severe impact on the health of the banking system. In December 2001, the Argentine authorities imposed a partial deposit freeze. With Argentina no longer in compliance with the conditions of the expanded IMF-supported program, the IMF decided to suspend disbursements. At the end of December, in a climate of severe political and social unrest, the country partially defaulted on its international obligations; in January 2002, it formally abandoned the convertibility regime. A sharp depreciation of the peso and a full-blown banking sector crisis ensued. By the end of 2002, the economy had contracted by 20 percent since the onset of the recession in 1998, with tremendous economic and social costs to the population.

Figure 2

B. Factors Contributing to the Crisis

While there are competing explanations as to the primary cause of the Argentine crisis, it is clear that several factors played a role in creating vulnerabilities, with changing relative importance over time. These include: (i) an excessively lax fiscal policy, particularly during times of rapid growth when substantial fiscal surpluses should have been achieved as a buffer against future downturns; (ii) the convertibility regime itself, which did not allow needed real exchange rate adjustment to take place through nominal depreciation; (iii) excessive and unpredictable swings in the volume of global capital flows to emerging market economies; (iv) the slow pace of structural reform in some critical areas, which hindered the ability of domestic wages and prices to adjust quickly; and (v) institutional and political factors which prevented the prompt implementation of corrective measures. Against this background, some additional factors helped to trigger the crisis and to exacerbate the impact of these underlying weaknesses: (vi) a series of adverse external shocks, including the appreciation of the U.S. dollar, the Russian default and the LTCM crisis, the devaluation of the Brazilian real, and the global economic slowdown; (vii) the impact of slow growth and high interest rates (resulting from higher risk premia on Argentine bonds) on the prospective path of the ratio of debt to GDP; and (viii) in the final stage of the crisis, a weakening of prudential defenses in the banking system, which contributed to the loss of confidence in the currency and complicated attempts to restore stability once the convertibility regime collapsed. It is possible that any one or a few of these factors would have been only a drag on growth and a potential source of vulnerabilities, but all these factors in combination proved to be sufficient to create a major crisis and to make the convertibility regime all but impossible to sustain.

(i) Fiscal policy

Many observers have held that fiscal policy was excessively lax, particularly in those years when rapid growth offered scope for a countercyclical fiscal policy that would have helped to reduce debt. Persistent deficits reflected the poor transparency of fiscal operations, widespread tax avoidance and evasion, and the limited ability of the federal government to control the expenditures of the provincial governments. Compounding these weaknesses, it is sometimes argued that irresponsible policies were pursued, such as using proceeds from privatization for current expenditures instead of debt reduction. As a result, when a recession hit in 1998, the debt stock had grown to such an extent that stabilizing it would have required a sharply procyclical fiscal adjustment, which may not have been realistic in the context.

(ii) The convertibility regime

Another common view challenges the choice of the convertibility regime itself, given the lack of price and wage flexibility and the country's geographical pattern of trade and vulnerability to external shocks. As a result, the convertibility regime did not allow the real effective exchange rate of the peso to depreciate when necessary. In particular, the strength of the U.S. dollar in the late 1990s and the devaluation of the Brazilian real in 1999 led to a sustained rise in Argentina's real effective exchange rate, which in turn caused a loss of competitiveness and stifled growth and exports. Moreover, convertibility obliged Argentina to align its monetary policy with that of the United States, despite cyclical differences between the two countries. According to this line of analysis, Argentina's fiscal policy might have been more sustainable if the convertibility regime had not been in place. Instead, as the exchange rate peg forced an increase in the debt service ratio by suppressing the growth of exports and widening the current account deficit, there was no politically feasible stance of fiscal policy that would have been compatible with the exchange rate regime, once the economy had slowed down.

(iii) Decline in capital flows

Some have argued that Argentina relied too much on capital inflows, rather than generating domestic savings, in part reflecting the relatively slow development of domestic financial markets. When there was a sharp reduction (or "sudden stop" as it is sometimes called) in global capital flows to emerging market economies in 1998, it became increasingly costly for Argentina to raise funds on international capital markets. Because of the convertibility regime, and because of the relatively small size of its export sector, Argentina could not easily adapt to the shock through a rapid depreciation of the real exchange rate. Thanks to careful management of maturity structure, the impact of the fall in inflows was not as sudden as it would have been had more of the debt been contracted at shorter maturities. Nevertheless, as adverse debt dynamics (see below) took their toll, eventually Argentina faced few options beyond restructuring the debt or outright default.

(iv) Structural reform

The structural rigidity of the Argentine economy—and the lack of reform to correct the problem—is another factor that has been cited as having contributed to the crisis. The convertibility regime required that real exchange rate adjustment take place through price changes, rather than through movements in the nominal exchange rate. This meant that, in the conditions facing Argentina from 1995 onwards, domestic prices and wages needed to fall in order to compensate for the appreciation of the U.S. dollar against other major currencies. Yet, after some efforts in the early 1990s, attempts to reform the labor market came to a virtual halt in the mid-1990s, and progress in the liberalization of other areas, such as product markets, foreign trade, utilities and infrastructure, was slow. Openness to trade was another area where structural reform may have been incomplete. While many direct and indirect trade barriers were removed, and while exports did grow steadily, by the end of the 1990s Argentina was still a relatively closed economy. This limited the country's ability to earn foreign exchange to repay its external debt. It also meant that a very large real depreciation was necessary to counteract shocks such as the strength of the U.S. dollar in the late 1990s and the global economic slowdown in 2001. Finally, the persistence of the current account deficit through the 1990s may itself have partly reflected structural inefficiencies.

(v) Institutional and political factors

Some have noted the institutional and political features of Argentina as factors that limited the ability of the federal government to take decisive actions when confronted with a crisis. Electoral politics, for example, led to compromises on needed fiscal adjustment in the provinces and on the structural reform agenda. In general, the considerable power of the provincial governments, in a context where provinces had been entrusted with major public expenditure responsibilities, greatly reduced the flexibility of fiscal policy. Corruption and other governance issues have also been cited as factors undermining the credibility of the authorities.

(vi) External shocks

It is often pointed out that Argentina benefited from the favorable global economic conditions that characterized much of the 1990s. When these conditions began to deteriorate toward the end of the decade, the impact on Argentina was severe, and all the more so because the convertibility regime and remaining structural rigidities prevented a flexible domestic policy response. Among the external shocks were the Russian/LTCM crises of 1998, which led to a reduction in capital flows to emerging market economies and an increase in risk premia; the devaluation of the Brazilian real, which had a negative impact on the competitiveness of Argentina's exports; the appreciation of the U.S. dollar against most other currencies in the late 1990s, which increased Argentina's real effective exchange rate; and the global economic slowdown that started in the beginning of 2001, which depressed the price of Argentina's main exports.

(vii) Debt dynamics

Given the past history of fiscal policy, debt dynamics began to have a life of its own, severely constraining the policy options available to the authorities. Many commentators emphasize that, after 1998, the combination of a large existing stock of external debt, rising country risk premia and sluggish growth caused the ratio of debt to GDP to rise uncontrollably. All of these factors fed upon one another, to the point where it would have been necessary for the authorities to run an unrealistically large primary surplus simply to keep the debt to GDP ratio from rising further.

(viii) The banking system

Until the depositor runs started to accelerate in the spring of 2001, the Argentine banking system was considered to be a model for emerging market economies in terms of prudential standards, capitalization and liquidity. The sound banking system, a product of sustained efforts by the authorities, was an important supporting element of the convertibility regime in which the ability of the central bank to serve as the lender of last resort was limited. By the end of 2001, however, the cumulative effects of several years' recession, a year's capital flight and a series of controversial policy moves had left the banking system vulnerable to any further blows to public confidence. It has been widely argued that the manner in which the authorities tried to manage the exit from convertibility—including the legally ambiguous measures to block deposits, and the forced conversion of dollar-denominated bank assets and liabilities into pesos at asymmetric rates—compounded these weaknesses. As a result, Argentina entered 2002 with not only a currency and sovereign debt crisis, but a banking crisis as well. This severely complicated efforts to resolve the multiple crises as quickly as possible.

III. Issues for Evaluation

The purpose of this evaluation is to draw lessons for the IMF from its involvement in Argentina during the convertibility regime and its immediate aftermath. In doing this, we will seek to answer the following overarching questions:

  • What was the IMF's diagnosis of conditions in Argentina and how did it evolve over time?

  • How was the IMF's diagnosis translated into program design, conditionality and financing decisions?

  • What were the roles of IMF staff, IMF management, the Executive Board, and the authorities of large shareholder governments in the formulation of IMF decisions?

  • How quickly and effectively were the lessons from previous crises (including the Mexican, East Asian and Brazilian crises) incorporated into policy advice, financing policies and decision-making procedures?

  • What was the influence of global and regional conditions, particularly the desire to prevent contagion to and from other emerging market economies, on the decisions made in regard to Argentina?

  • Were the views and preferences of national authorities given too much, too little or an appropriate amount of consideration in program design? In other words, was the proper balance struck between "ownership" and the objectives of the IMF, in cases where these were not in alignment?
  • How effective were the IMF's policy advice and conditionality in influencing the policies actually pursued by the authorities? To what extent was insufficient implementation of agreed policies the cause of the problem?

  • What have been the lessons drawn by the IMF from the crisis to date? Should more or different lessons be learned?

In what follows, we present a list of specific issues to be addressed in the evaluation. These issues can be divided into two broad categories, corresponding to the two related but distinct phases of IMF involvement: first, the precrisis period of 1991-2000, and second, the crisis and its immediate aftermath, 2000-2002.

A. The Precrisis Period, 1991-2000

From the establishment of the convertibility regime in 1991 until late 2000, the IMF saw its primary role as providing a supportive environment for the success of convertibility through its financing and policy advice. The emphasis of the advice was on the strengthening of the financial system, the implementation of structural reforms, and the adoption of an appropriate fiscal policy stance. Among the issues to be considered are:

  • The convertibility regime. What were the IMF's initial views on the convertibility regime and how did they evolve over time? Did it view the convertibility regime as a sustainable system, given Argentina's economic and structural characteristics, including its openness and trading pattern? What were the IMF's views on when and how to exit from the fixed exchange rate peg? Did it have, and discuss with the authorities, an exit strategy? What was the IMF's assessment of Argentina's real effective exchange rate over the period? Were the IMF's views on these issues similar to those of the Argentine authorities or market participants?

  • Fiscal policy. How thoroughly did the IMF analyze the stance of fiscal policy? For example, did it fully take into account off-budget items (if any), provincial finances, deferred payments, the nonrecurring nature of some receipts, pension reform, etc.? How did it view the fiscal impact of the pension reform? What advice was given, through surveillance and technical assistance, in the areas of tax administration, fiscal federalism and fiscal transparency? How adequately did it analyze debt sustainability, and how was this analysis translated into advice on fiscal policy? What was the impact of this advice, and what factors determined the strength of this impact?

  • External debt inflows. How aware was the IMF of vulnerabilities inherent in borrowing in foreign currency? Why was there a large accumulation of external debt when fiscal deficits were seemingly modest? What were the underlying assumptions about the sustainability of capital inflows and determinants of Argentina's sovereign spread? What was the quality of dialogue with the private sector in assessing how the markets might react to adverse economic developments?

  • Structural reform. How successful did the IMF view the initial round of structural reforms in the labor market, privatization and other competitiveness enhancing areas? How did the IMF collaborate with the World Bank in Argentina's structural reform program? How did the IMF react to the apparent halt of initial gains in structural reform?

  • Institutional and Political Factors. What was the IMF's analysis of the ways in which Argentina's institutional weaknesses and political process conditioned economic policy making? Was the IMF candid in discussing corruption, tax evasion, and other governance issues? How much did the IMF analyze the political feasibility of the policies it was advocating? Did structural conditionality appropriately address Argentina's chronic institutional weaknesses?

  • Vulnerabilities in the banking system. What were the IMF's initial views of Argentine's banking system? How did the IMF contribute to the strengthening of the banking system through policy advice and technical assistance? Was the IMF aware of latent vulnerabilities arising from financial dollarization, exposure to the public sector, and the limitation on lender of last resort support? Did it have an estimate of the private sector balance sheet, and consider how this might affect the banking system in the event of a major shock?

  • Official financing. What was the rationale for continued financial support, particularly after macroeconomic stabilization had largely been achieved in 1993, and how was the level of access determined? Was there an exit strategy from IMF financing? How did the IMF's views on key economic policy issues influence program design? Was conditionality adequately supportive of the IMF's policy advice? Given the large number of waivers granted to Argentina over the period, was the IMF's appraisal of performance under its programs suitably rigorous? What was the impact of successive IMF-supported programs on private capital flows and did they create moral hazard? What was the role of IMF financing in helping Argentina to weather the crises that affected Mexico in 1994-95, East Asia in 1997-98, Russia in 1998 and Brazil in 1998-99? Were the criteria for access to exceptional finance (greater than three times the member's IMF quota) followed? Would the size of access have been justified if the criteria adjusted subsequently had been in force at the time?

  • Regional and global factors. Did the IMF adequately take account of events in Brazil and elsewhere in Latin America in formulating its analysis of developments in and prospects for Argentina? Did the IMF attempt to formulate a consistent view of developments across different countries in the region? How did concerns about the implications of a crisis in Argentina for other emerging economies worldwide affect IMF decisions? Were such concerns justified?

  • Transparency and Data Dissemination. Most IMF staff reports related to its Argentina programs, especially in the later years, were released immediately to the public. What impact did this have on the quality of the IMF's policy advice, the candor of the staff's assessments, and market views of developments? Did IMF staff have adequate access to crucial data required to make proper diagnosis?

B. The Crisis and Its Immediate Aftermath, 2000- 2002

When Argentina's ability to access international capital markets underwent a significant deterioration at the end of 2000, the role of the IMF shifted more towards crisis management. At several points in the year that followed, the IMF was faced with a critical dilemma: whether to provide financing, thereby averting a crisis but also prolonging a potentially unsustainable situation; or whether to end its support, thereby unleashing unpredictable consequences which could potentially spread to other emerging market economies. For each of the key decisions, the evaluation will attempt to determine how the IMF viewed this dilemma, and how it attempted to resolve it through the design of the financing and policy package. In addition, it will assess how the decision was reached and whether the alternatives were adequately considered. Here, the evaluation will duly consider the respective roles played by IMF staff, management, and the Executive Board. The following issues regarding the key financing decisions taken during this period merit particular attention:

  • The December 2000 decision to provide exceptional access. Did Argentina receive financial support beyond its capacity to pay? What was the role of private sector involvement (PSI) in the program, and were the assumptions about the impact of the program in "catalyzing" a reversal of capital outflows reasonable? What were the alternatives, and how were they considered in reaching the decision? Did the decision taken have a reasonable chance of success? Was there a contingency plan?

  • The program review in May 2001. Following its standard procedures, the IMF Board reviewed the Argentina program in May 2001 and decided to continue disbursements, even though, because of the worsening fiscal situation, Argentina was not in compliance with many of the conditions of the program. What considerations entered into this decision? What was the IMF's view of the policy program being pursued at the time, including plans to modify the mechanisms of the convertibility system, the scheme to use taxes and subsidies to reverse the impact of the dollar-peso peg on trade, and plans to swap outstanding debt for longer maturity instruments?

  • The September 2001 decision to augment the package. What were the objectives of the enlargement, and were they realistic? How did the IMF view the authorities' "zero-deficit law," and what role did this play in the decision? What were the alternatives, and how were they considered in reaching the decision? What was the role of major shareholders in formulating and approving the financing package? Why was the strategy of attempting to encourage a private-sector debt restructuring unsuccessful? Did the package only finance and provide more time for capital flight?

  • The December 2001 decision to withhold further disbursements. What contributed to the decision to "pull the plug" then? What were the alternatives considered? Could a similar decision have been made at a different date at lower cost? In particular, what was the IMF's view of the attempted debt exchange, and why were disbursements halted before the second stage of the exchange could be completed? Should the IMF have pursued a different approach to private sector involvement, which could have averted the default? What was the nature of the IMF's involvement in the subsequent controversial measures taken by the authorities in early 2002? How did the actual consequences of the default and devaluation compare to the staff's expectations?

IV. The Methodology and timeline of the Evaluation

The purpose of this evaluation is to understand the factors that determined IMF decisions during the period under review and, based on this analysis, to draw relevant lessons as to how the IMF's policies and procedures could be improved. The evaluation will rely on the IMF's internal and published documents to assess the evolution of institutional views and analysis. This will be supplemented by interviews with IMF staff, officials of the Argentine government and central bank, and other key decision makers in the IMF, its shareholder governments and the private sector; a review of the academic literature and public discussion; and analyses of data, including a detailed review of fiscal accounts, comparative analysis of fiscal policy between Argentina and other emerging market economies, assessment of macroeconomic projections in program documents, and a simulation of debt dynamics. In order to obtain a broad perspective on issues, views will also be sought from academic and private-sector experts in North and South America, Europe and Asia, as well as interested parties in civil society.

In addressing the questions and issues identified in this paper, we recognize that any economic outcome is a result of a complex sequence of decisions that are made subject to available information and exogenous factors (see Figure 3 for a schematic representation of stages and elements of decision making in economic policy).3 This means that it is often not possible to ascribe responsibility to any one decision; establishing accountability is even more difficult. For analytical ease and convenience, therefore, the evaluation will be guided by the following criteria at each stage, by taking available information, exogenous factors, and the policies followed by the authorities as given:

(i) At stage one: whether the IMF's diagnosis incorporated all the relevant information available at the time and was based on reasonable macroeconomic forecasts;

(ii) At stage two: whether additional information would have led to a different (and more accurate) diagnosis;

(iii) At stage three: whether the IMF's available instruments (i.e., surveillance and financing facilities) were used in a way that maximized their impact;

(iv) At stage four: whether program-related decisions correctly considered all relevant factors, including available alternatives and the risks they entailed; and

(v) At stage five: whether different instruments or decisions might have led to a superior outcome.

By their very nature, some of our judgments would require use of counterfactual analysis, and any conclusions drawn from such analysis can only be tentative. Even so, with these limitations in mind, we anticipate that the approach to evaluation proposed here will enable us to identify specific areas in which there is room for improvement in the IMF's practices and procedures.

Comments on this paper and inputs relating to the substance of the issues raised therein are welcome and should be submitted through the IEO's website (www.imf.org/ieo) or by email (ieo@imf.org). It is expected that the evaluation report will be drafted toward the end of the year and will be released to the public, following discussion by the IMF Executive Board, sometime in 2004.

Figure 3

Bibliography

Allen, Mark, 2003, "Some Lessons from the Argentine Crisis: A Fund Staff View," in The Crisis That Was Not Prevented, edited by Jan Joost Teunissen and Age Akkerman (The Hague: Forum on Debt and Development), pp. 120-150.

Antonelli, Eduardo, 2002, "La Inflación en la Argentina: Análisis y Evidencia Empírica, 1900-2000," paper presented at the conference XXVII Reunion Annual de la Asociación Argentina de Economía Política, Tucuman, November.

Artana, Daniel, Ricardo López Murphy and Fernando Navajar, 2003, "A Fiscal Policy Agenda," in After the Washington Concensus: Restauring Growth and Reform in Latin America, edited by Pedro Pablo Kuczynski and John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics), pp. 75-101.

Arriazu, Ricardo Héctor, 2003, Lecciones de la Crisis Aregentina: Bases Programáticas para un Esquema de Desarrollo Sustentable (Buenos Aires: El Ateneo).

Blejer, Mario I., Alejandro Henke, and Eduardo Levy-Yeyati, 2002, "The Argentine Crisis: Issues for Discussion," paper presented at the workshop "The Argentine Crisis," Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research, November 26.

Boughton, James, 2001, Silent Revolution: The International Monetary Fund, 1979-1989 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

Bulacio, José and Hugo Ferullo, 2001, "El Déficit Fiscal en Argentina y sus Consecuencias Macroeconómicas," unpublished, Universidad Nacional de Tucuman.

Caballero, Ricardo, and Rudiger Dornbusch, 2002, "Argentina: A Rescue Plan That Works," unpublished, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Corrales, Javier, 2002, "The Politics of Argentina's Meltdown," World Policy Journal, Fall, pp. 29-42.

Calvo, Guillermo A., 1998, "Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops," Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 1 (November), pp. 35-54.

Cavallo, Domingo, and Joaquin A. Cottani, 1997, "Argentina's Convertibility Plan and the IMF," American Economic Review, Vol. 87 (May), pp. 17-22.

Curia, Eduardo L., 1997, La Convertibilidad y sus Desvios. Entre el Modelo y el Programa (Buenos Aires: Centro de Análisis Social y Económico).

Conesa, Eduardo, 2000, Qué Pasa en la Economía Argentina (Buenos Aires, Bogotá, Caracas, and Mexico City: Ed. Macchi).

De Beaufort Wijnholds, J. Onno, 2003, "The Argentine Drama: A View from the IMF Board," in The Crisis That Was Not Prevented, edited by Jan Joost Teunissen and Age Akkerman (The Hague: Forum on Debt and Development), pp. 101-119.

De la Torre, Augusto, Augusto Eduardo Levy Yeyati, and Sergio L. Schmukler, 2002, "Argentina's Financial Crisis: Floating Money, Sinking Banking," unpublished, World Bank.

______, 2003, "Living and Dying with Hard Pegs: The Rise and Fall of Argentina's Currency Board," Economia, forthcoming.

Edwards, Sebastian, 2002, "The Argentine Debt Crisis of 2001-2002: A Chronology and Some Key Policy Issues," unpublished, University of California, Los Angeles.

Escudé, Guillermo and Andrew Powell, 2001, "The Argentine Fixed Exchange Rate System: The First 10 Years," paper presented at the IMF Seminar "Exchange Rate Regimes: Hard Peg or Free Floating?"

Escudé, Guillermo, 2002, "The Great Exchange Rate Debate After Argentina," Working Paper No.9257, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Feldstein, Martin, 2002, "Argentina's Fall: Lessons from the Latest Financial Crisis," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 81 (March/April), pp. 8-14.

Frenkel, Roberto, 2003, "Globalización y crisis finacnieras en América Latina," CEDES, Buenos Aires.

Fundación de Investigaciones Económicas Latinoamericanas (FIEL), 1999, "Productivity, Competitiveness and Economic Reforms in Argentina: Was It Enough?" Buenos Aires.

González Fraga, Javier, 2002, "Convertibility and the Argentine Banking Crisis," paper presented at the conference "Russia and Argentina: Lessons from the Experience," Moscow, November.

Hanke, Steve H, and Kurt Schuler, 2002, "What Went Wrong in Argentina?" Central Banking Journal, Vol. 12, Number 3.

Hausmann, Ricardo, 2001, "After 10 Years of Convertibility Should Argentina Move to Greener Pastures?" paper presented at the conference organized by the Banco Central de la Republica Argentina, Buenos Aires.

Hausmann, Ricardo, and Andrés Velasco, 2002, "The Argentine Collapse: Hard Money's Soft Underbelly," unpublished, Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.

Krueger, Anne, 2002, "Crisis Prevention and Resolution: Lessons from Argentina," paper presented at the conference "The Argentina Crisis," Cambridge, Massachusetts, National Bureau of Economic Research, July 17.

Lagos, Martin, 2002, "The Argentine Banking Crisis 2001-2002," report prepared for the Argentine Bankers Association.

Llach, Juan, 2001, "Un Nuevo Contrato Fiscal Federal. Una Reforma para Mejorar la Competitividad, la Correspondencia Fiscal, el Federalimo y la Democracia Representativa," unpublished, IAE, Universidad Austral.

Machinea, Jose Luis, 2002, "Currency Crisis: A Practitioner's View," paper presented at the Brookings Trade Conference, Washington, Brookings Institution, May.

McCndless, George, M. Florencia Gabrielli, and M. Josefina Ouillet, 2002, "Determinando las Causas de las Corridas Bancarias en Argentina durante 2001," unpublished, Banco Central de la Republica Argentina, Buenos Aires.

Moras, Ireneo, 2001, "Estabilidad de Precios y Crecimiento Sostenido: Convertibilidad Más Flexible o Meta Inflacionaria," unpublished, UADE.

Mussa, Michael, 2002, "Argentina and the Fund: From Triumph to Tragedy," Policy Analyses in International Economics No. 67 (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

O'Connell, Arturo, 2002, "The Recent Crisis of the Argentine Economy: Some Elements and Background," paper presented at the METU Conference, Ankara, September.

Perry, Guillermo, and Luis Servèn, 2002, "The Anatomy and Physiology of a Multiple Crisis: Why Was Argentina Special and What Can We Learn from It?" Latin America and Caribbean Regional Office, World Bank.

Powell, Andrew, 2002, "The Avoidable Argentine Crisis: Bad Luck, Bad Economics, Bad Politics, Bad Advice," paper presented at the Brookings Trade Conference, Washington, Brookings Institution, May.

Rial, Osvaldo H., 2001, La Dictadura Económica. Testimonios de un Industrial (Buenos Aires: Galerna).

Rodriguez, Carlos A., Javier Bolzico, Pablo Druck, Alejandro Henk, José Rutman, Walter Sosa Escudero, and Streb Jorge, 2001, "Credit Constraints Facing Firms in Argentina," unpublished, CEMA.

Rodriguez, Carlos A. and Javier Ortiz, 2001, "Nuevas Perspectivas sobre los Efectos de las Políticas Monetarias y Fiscales en un Régimen de Tipo de Cambio Fijo: Interacciones entre el Riesgo País y el Nivel de Reservas Internacionales," CEMA.

Rodrik, Dani, 2002, "Reform in Argentina, Take Two. Trade Rout," The New Republic, January 2.

Rossi, C. E. Rodolfo, 2003, El Colapso de la Convertibilidad Monetaria (Buenos Aires: Ed. Dunken).

Teijeiro, Mario, 1996, La política Fiscal Durante la Convertibilidad, Centro de Estudios Públicos, Buenos Aires.

, 2001, "Una Vez Más, la Política Fiscal," Centro de Estudios Públicos, Buenos Aires.

Teunissen, Jan Joost and Age Akkerman (eds.), 2003, The Crisis That Was Not Prevented (The Hague: Forum on Debt and Development).

Tietmeyer, Hans, Luis Angel Rojo, John Crow, Andrew Crockett, 2002, "Economic and Financial Issues Facing Argentina," Report to the Government of Argentina and the IMF by a Panel of Independent Advisers.

United States Congress, Joint Economic Committee, 2003. "Argentina's Economic Crisis: Causes and Cures," Washington, June.

World Bank, Latin America and Caribbean Regional Office, 2002, "Argentina: What Happened? A Retrospective Review," unpublished.

Weisbrot, Mark, and Dean Baker, 2002, "What Happened to Argentina?" Briefing Paper, Center for Economic and Policy Research.

Table 1. Argentina: Key Economic Indicators

  1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002

Real GDP growth (percent) 10.5 10.3 6.3 5.8 -2.8 5.5 8.1 3.9 -3.4 -0.8 -4.4 -11.0
  Real private consumption (percent) . . . . . . . . . 6.1 -4.4 5.5 9.0 3.5 -2.0 -0.7 -5.7 -14.4
  Real government consumption (percent) . . . . . . . . . 0.4 0.8 2.2 3.2 3.4 2.6 0.6 -2.1 -5.1
  Real fixed investment (percent) . . . . . . . . . 13.7 -13.1 8.9 17.7 6.5 -12.6 -6.8 -15.7 -36.1
              
Inflation (CPI, Dec/Dec, percent) 84.0 17.6 7.4 3.9 1.6 0.1 0.3 0.7 -1.8 -0.7 -1.5 41.0
Money (M1, Dec/Dec, percent, in pesos) 148.6 49.0 33.0 8.2 1.6 14.6 12.8 0.0 1.6 -9.2 -20.1 80.9
Quasi- money (Dec/Dec, percent, in pesos) 136.8 71.4 54.3 22.3 -4.7 20.8 31.2 14.5 4.9 5.0 -19.2 3.4
              
Current Account (in billions US$) -0.4 -6.5 -8.0 -11.2 -5.2 -6.8 -12.2 -14.5 -11.9 -8.8 -4.4 8.6
(In percent of GDP) -0.2 -2.8 -3.4 -4.3 -2.0 -2.5 -4.2 -4.9 -4.2 -3.1 -1.7 8.3
Total Exports growth (in US$, percent) -2.1 3.4 8.5 17.8 28.9 13.6 9.0 0.7 -10.5 11.8 -0.6 -8.2
Total Imports growth (in US$, percent) 68.3 58.8 30.3 11.3 -4.6 15.8 24.1 3.4 -15.3 0.4 -16.6 -51.9
              
External debt (in billions of US$) 62.3 62.7 72.2 85.7 98.6 109.8 124.9 141.4 144.5 146.3 140.3 136.6
(In percent of GDP) 32.9 27.4 30.5 33.3 38.2 40.3 42.7 47.3 51.0 51.5 52.2 132.6
Debt service ratio / exports (percent) 33.6 27.5 30.9 25.2 30.2 39.4 50.0 57.6 75.4 70.8 66.3 . . .
              
International reserves (in billions of US$) 6.0 10.0 13.8 14.3 14.3 18.1 22.3 24.8 26.3 25.2 14.6 10.5
Exchange rate (peso/$, end-period) 0.9985 0.9905 0.9985 0.9995 1.0000 0.9995 0.9995 0.9995 0.9995 0.9995 0.9995 3.3200
Real effective exchange rate (end-period)1 140.5 165.5 178.0 169.5 163.2 163.7 176.3 171.2 178.2 185.6 185.7 72.0
Terms of Trade ( percent change) 7.6 6.1 -7.8 14.4 -4.5 9.9 0.2 -5.1 -8.4 7.5 -5.8 -16.0
              
Primary balance (in millions of pesos) -483 1,043 3,685 2,890 1,156 -1,420 -1,580 2,388 1,413 -2,672 1,709 -2,844
  Federal government (in millions of pesos) 371 2,278 3,928 4,177 2,776 1,107 -1,392 1,450 2,187 21 3,150 1,295
  Provincial government (in millions of pesos) -854 -1,235 -243 -1,287 -1,620 -2,527 -188 938 -774 -2,693 -1,441 -4,139
Overall balance (in millions of pesos) -1,190 -1,464 710 -151 -2,607 -6,224 -7,212 -4,396 -6,418 -12,304 -9,781 -15,445
  Federal government (in millions of pesos) -245 37 1,307 1,607 -416 -2,976 -6,020 -4,282 -4,453 -8,180 -6,468 -8,875
  Provincial government (in millions of pesos) -945 -1,501 -596 -1,758 -2,191 -3,248 -1,192 -114 -1,964 -4,125 -3,313 -6,570

Source: IMF database; the Ministry of Economy of Argentina; and Global Development Finance.
1Average of 1990=100.



Footnotes

1The financing arrangements included two extended arrangements under the Extended Fund Facility (EFFs) approved in 1992 and 1998, and two Standby Arrangements (SBAs) approved in 1996 and 2000. The 1998 EFF was treated as precautionary, involving no intention on the part of the authorities to draw on the resources made available under the arrangement. The 2000 SBA, in addition to resources under the credit tranches, also made available to Argentina resources under the Supplemental Reserve Facility (SRF).
2The choice of this period leaves out issues related to the role of the IMF in Argentina's subsequent economic reconstruction and recovery. The IEO's terms of reference do not allow us to evaluate issues that have direct bearing on the IMF's ongoing operations.
3Figure 3 is only illustrative; it is not meant to be an exact representation of the complex decision making tree.