|
|
|
December 15, 2000
|
Foreword | |||||||||||||||||||||
The reform of price subsidies may
be necessary not only to improve efficiency, but also to facilitate pro-poor
economic growth and release resources for critical social services for
the poor. At the same time, increases in prices for basic commodities
and petroleum products can be associated with real income losses for the
poor as well as political unrest in some cases. This guide provides guidance
to policymakers on how to design and implement sound price-subsidy reforms
that take into account both economic and social considerations.
This guide draws on the experience with the reform of price subsidies in 28 countries. It discusses economic and political considerations in price-subsidy reform and makes several recommendations concerning the speed of reform and social protection mechanisms. Rapid reform requires a favorable political and economic environment. In the absence of this, reform should be implemented gradually. The social impact of reform can be limited by establishing cost-effective and well-targeted temporary social protection mechanisms. Governments can reduce the risk of political disruption by distributing the initial burden of reform fairly and by clearly explaining the cost and benefits to the public. The authors would like to thank Stanley Fischer, Vito Tanzi, Peter Heller, and Ke-young Chu as well as staff of various IMF departments for helpful comments on earlier versions. Administrative support was ably provided by Cecilia Pineda, Larry Hartwig, and Amy Deigh. David Driscoll of the IMF’s External Relations Department edited the manuscript and Gail Berre coordinated production of the publication. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
I. Overview | |||||||||||||||||||||
1. The reform of price subsidies has been a key element of IMF- supported programs in many countries. These reforms have brought prices of subsidized items closer to their market-clearing levels and have sought to target any remaining subsidies to the needy. Reform is typically undertaken in the context of macroeconomic adjustment, and its major aim is to achieve fiscal savings consistent with stabilization of prices and exchange rates. Reform of price subsidies may also improve allocative efficiency and promote economic growth, but can—at least in the short run—have adverse social and political effects. These effects can be mitigated or eliminated by establishing social safety nets and, in some cases, by gradually phasing out subsidies. 2. This guide is intended to assist policymakers in achieving the fiscal benefits of price-subsidy reform with minimal social disruption. To this end, the guide draws on the experience of a wide range of countries and lists factors that must be considered in the design of price-subsidy reform. The countries met at least one of the following criteria: the budgetary cost of the subsidies was significant before reform; the Fiscal Affairs Department of the IMF provided technical assistance on reforming price subsidies or assigned a fiscal economist to the country; or price-subsidy reform was a major element of the IMF-supported program. The 28 countries examined are listed in Appendix 1. 3. Section 2 of this guide presents possible reform options; Section 3 provides a checklist of considerations in the design and implementation of price-subsidy reform; Section 4 discusses political considerations; and Section 5 draws key lessons. The appendices describe the nature of price subsidies, discuss different price subsidies (Appendix 2), and illustrate how the impact of price-subsidy reform on real household incomes could be assessed (Appendix 3). |
|||||||||||||||||||||
II. Economic Issues in the Reform of Price Subsidies | |||||||||||||||||||||
4. Subsidy reform entails price liberalization or adjusting controlled prices of subsidized goods and services, often during macroeconomic adjustment. The economic goals are to correct fiscal imbalances and to improve allocative efficiency. Since the removal of subsidies may have adverse consequences for the poor, these effects must be analyzed and, to the extent feasible, mitigated or offset. In this context, the principal—and interrelated—issues that arise are the speed of price-subsidy reform and the options for protecting the real consumption of the poor. Speed of Price-Subsidy Reform 5. There is a trade-off between rapidly cutting budget-financed subsidies and avoiding an adverse impact on the poor. A one-time adjustment of prices to eliminate subsidies can yield immediate budget savings and quickly correct distortions in resource allocation. However, it can also result in a sudden and significant drop in standards of living, especially for low-income households. The need to compensate households implies that fiscal savings from price-subsidy reform are usually less than the amount spent on generalized subsidies before the reform. 6. Gradual reform is not without drawbacks. Apart from the fact that it takes longer to reap budgetary and economic gains, progress under gradual reform may falter, or even be reversed. A number of small price increases may engender more public opposition to continuing reforms than a single large increase. In addition, the continued presence during the phase-out period of institutions needed to administer the price subsidies contributes to the risk of a reversal of the reforms (this was a factor in the reappearance of the bread subsidy in Jordan in 1999, after five years of gradual reform).1 Finally, a gradual approach may fail if it is adopted to postpone politically difficult reforms. Such failure can be avoided by publicly adopting a detailed timetable of measures. 7. The speed of price-subsidy reform depends on a number of elements (see Box 1). They are:
Temporary Mechanisms to Protect the Poor 8. Poor households can be temporarily protected from the effects of reforming implicit and explicit price-subsidies by:
9. These temporary measures should be phased out and eventually subsumed under existing or new social assistance programs as the economic adjustment envisaged under economic reforms is completed. As the social impact of price-subsidy reform dissipates over time, the imperative of providing a coherent system of social protection for the poor overtakes the need to provide special protection to those affected by the reform. In practice, however, it has proven difficult to phase out temporary social safety nets.3 To avoid this, their temporary nature should be addressed at the outset, through public pronouncements and, where feasible, sunset provisions. Alternatively, the cash compensation or targeted subsidy, as well as the qualifying criteria, can be held constant in nominal terms. In this case, the real value of the transfer and the number of recipients will decline over time with increases in the price level and the growth of nominal household incomes (e.g., as happened with the food stamp program in Sri Lanka during 1979–82; Edirisinghe, 1988). 10. During reform of producer subsidies, selected small producers and workers can be compensated for lower output prices or higher input prices by targeted cash transfers. Producers can be given income support (e.g., in relation to the size of landholding in agriculture). Unemployed workers can receive severance payments or benefits from an existing or adapted unemployment scheme. Targeting of Compensation and Consumer-Price Subsidies 11. The primary issues in deciding how to target compensation and price subsidies are the ability to identify the poor, the administrative capacity to deliver assistance, and the political support for the targeting scheme (see also Chu and Gupta, 1998a). The first two issues are discussed below and in Section 3; the third issue is taken up in Section 4. 12. The following economic objectives should guide the design of a targeting mechanism:
13. The goals of efficiency and equity can best be served if the government can limit its assistance to those truly in need. This requires the ability to design and implement an effective means test. A means test sets an income threshold above which benefits are phased out (see Box 2 for its application to Ukraine). Simple means tests do not value in-kind or seasonal income, or consider other individual adjustments. More sophisticated tests adjust family income according to, for instance, family size or the costs of major items such as housing and major medical expenses. A means test should be graduated, with benefits declining as income rises, to avoid discontinuities in labor supply. 14. Means tests have been difficult to implement in developing countries and transition economies because of the difficulty of observing income earned in the informal sector. A clustering of incomes around a narrow range, implying a large change in the number of beneficiaries with a small change in the threshold, can also add to design and administration difficulties. In countries that are devolving responsibilities to lower levels of government, weak administrative capacity of subnational jurisdictions can limit the effective implementation of transfer programs. 15. In countries that are unable to establish an efficient means test, the poor have to be targeted indirectly.5 Table 1 provides stylized examples of how to choose among the indirect targeting options listed below (see also Chu and Gupta, 1998b).
Table: Stylized Options for Targeting
Note: In all cases, the subsidy to be reformed is assumed to be a generalized subsidy for basic food staples. The targeting options are meant to provide an indication of what may be appropriate under different circumstances. The choice would crucially depend on prevailing conditions, such as the incidence of corruption and available financing.
16. The choice among targeting options depends on the ability and willingness of governments to target subsidies and cash transfers. In cases where the country lacks both the administrative capacity to target price subsidies and social protection instruments that can be quickly adapted to compensate the poor, self-targeting mechanisms or provision of a limited subsidy to all are likely to be the only available options for compensating the poor, at least in the short run. Box 3 lists selected examples of countries where price-subsidy reform has been successful. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
III. Checklist of Economic Considerations in Price-Subsidy Reform9 | |||||||||||||||||||||
17. Based on the above discussion, policymakers should do the following to the extent information is available:10 18. Assess the nature of existing subsidies—their objectives, beneficiaries, administrative mechanisms, and costs. The analysis of current subsidies should be the starting point and should include an assessment of their economic rationale and efficiency in achieving their objectives. Special attention should be given to identifying the extent of implicit subsidies, which in contrast to explicit subsidies, cannot be easily gleaned from the budget. In the case of producer subsidies, design considerations are different. The goal of producer subsidy policy is to protect incomes of producers and support employment. In such cases, as noted in Appendix 2, output prices are set above market-clearing levels. Compensatory measures should then be targeted at smaller, less wealthy, producers and those rendered unemployed by reforms. 19. Assess the socioeconomic and demographic characteristics of the population affected by higher consumer prices, particularly the poor. The poor may be clustered in certain socioeconomic groups or regions. For instance, in Europe and Central Asia, single mothers, families with many children, pensioners living alone, and workers with little or outdated education are very often poor (Grootaert and Braithwaite, 1998); much of the poverty in Africa, on the other hand, is concentrated in rural areas (Demery, 1999). Such information is typically available from the World Bank’s Poverty Assessments and household surveys. The poverty line is crucial for assessing the characteristics of the poor. In the design of social safety nets, the usual practice has been to use country-specific poverty lines, rather than international poverty lines defined in terms of daily consumption measured in U.S. dollars in purchasing-power-parity terms. 20. Assess the gains from price-subsidy reform. These would include improved resource allocation (e.g., improved availability of price- controlled items), resource savings that could finance critical public services, or reduce the deficit or taxes, and the beneficial impact on real incomes of some households (see below). 21. Examine the short-term impact of increasing prices of consumer items on real household incomes, particularly the incomes of the poor. Both the direct and indirect effects of changes in the price of subsidized items must be considered by following these steps:11
22. Examine the macroeconomic stance. Typically, price-subsidy reform is undertaken at a time of fiscal consolidation to help achieve macroeconomic stability. The scope of the compensation scheme and the speed and extent of the reform must be consistent with these overall policy targets. Macroeconomic policy should also take into account the impact of price-subsidy reform. The reduction of consumer-price subsidies will be reflected in a one-time increase in prices. Monetary and fiscal policies should prevent these price adjustments from triggering a period of sustained higher inflation through, for example, a price-wage spiral. 23. Examine the capacity to use, on a temporary basis, existing social protection instruments to compensate the poor. These instruments may include formal social security arrangements, including social insurance (such as public pensions and unemployment insurance), family allowances, and social assistance. In cases where speed is of the essence, the administrative structure of existing social security programs can, in principle, be used to transfer benefits quickly to those poor individuals and households affected by the price-subsidy reform. It will be important, though, to ensure that such use of existing social security programs is temporary and that any additional cost is funded separately. Since these instruments—particularly social insurance programs—do not have poverty reduction as their principal aim, they may need to be adapted, a process that has often encountered political resistance, especially in transition economies. Finally, although some countries—particularly many transition economies—have a variety of such instruments, others— notably in Africa—may lack them. 24. Assess the interaction with other elements of the adjustment program. The adverse impact of price-subsidy reform can be exacerbated by other adjustment measures (e.g., an exchange rate devaluation and civil service reform). Specific measures, though not designed to compensate for price-subsidy reform, may help to ameliorate its adverse impact on certain population groups (e.g., the provision of severance pay to assist those laid off from civil service and public enterprises). On the other hand, in a number of transition economies, enterprises provide in-kind subsidies to their workers (e.g., for housing, day care, school, health care, sports, and food) (Hu, 1998). Enterprise reform can deprive households of such in-kind benefits, and this fact should be reflected in the design of safety nets. 25. Assess governance and administrative capacity. In many countries, weak governance and administrative capacity hamper the targeting and delivery of benefits. Weak governance can divert and waste resources allocated for price subsidies. Weak administrative capacity reflects the lack of cost-effective mechanisms to channel income transfers or targeted price subsidies to the designated population groups, and can be rooted in such factors as insufficient information on the poor and lack of equipment. Even where administrative capacity exists, targeting and delivery can be difficult. Determining eligibility on the basis of income may lead to mistargeting benefits if the administrative capacity is weak. Furthermore, incomes change over time and frequent updates of income data are costly (Van de Walle, 1998). For example, the cost of administering a means-tested rice-subsidy program in India’s Andhra Pradesh state in 1996 was Rs 1.75 for every rupee reaching the poor, and another Rs 3.6 were lost in leakage to the nonpoor (Radhakrishna and others, 1997). 26. Take account of available financing. The reform of explicit subsidies is usually undertaken to achieve, inter alia, budgetary savings. Depending on the size of required fiscal adjustment, part of those savings can be used for targeted programs. On occasion, access to foreign funds and commodity assistance may provide additional resources for compensatory measures. 27. Assess the impact on the environment. Price-subsidy reform is usually, but not always, beneficial for the environment (Gupta, Miranda, and Parry, 1995). Input subsidies for pesticides, fertilizers, and irrigation can be harmful for the environment. They also provide incentives for land clearance, which can lead to soil erosion. Subsidies for energy may contribute to global warming, acid rain, and respiratory and other health problems. On the other hand, subsidies for kerosene have been defended because they tend to benefit the poor and they can reduce reliance on firewood and protect forests.12 However, the most efficient way to internalize environmental costs and benefits is to penalize behavior that harms the environment, as with a carbon tax, rather than subsidize alternatives to this harmful behavior. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
IV. Political Considerations | |||||||||||||||||||||
28. When reform targets benefits to truly needy families, less needy families will suffer. The latter families may be part of politically powerful groups. If governments perceive the risk of political fallout—including apprehension about violent protest—as too large, they may be deterred from implementing reforms. In some countries—Ecuador in 1998–99, for instance—the government’s popularity was eroded in the wake of the implementation of reforms. 29. As noted above, political considerations influence the speed of reform. These considerations include (see also Box 1):
30. In general, violent reactions to price-subsidy reform are the exception rather than the norm, and often are not triggered by the reform alone (Box 4). Subsidy reductions that have touched off civil unrest are those for staple foods, such as bread (Egypt, Jordan, and Morocco), maize (Zambia and Zimbabwe), and petroleum products (Ecuador, Indonesia, Nigeria, and Venezuela). 31. To assess the political risks associated with price-subsidy reform, policymakers should, to the extent feasible:
32. Even if price-subsidy reform is associated with considerable risk of political disruption, certain policies can ameliorate those risks:
|
|||||||||||||||||||||
V. Key Lessons | |||||||||||||||||||||
33. Speed
34. Social protection mechanisms
35. Political disruption
|
|||||||||||||||||||||
Appendix 1: List of Examined Countries14 | |||||||||||||||||||||
|
|||||||||||||||||||||
36. A price subsidy reduces the consumer price of a good or service below what it would be in the absence of the subsidy (consumer subsidy) or increases the price received by a producer above its market level (producer subsidy). In practice, consumer subsidies are often implemented with price controls, resulting in shortages of the subsidized item. Producer subsidies, on the other hand, are often administered through producer support prices. When support prices are set too high, there is an oversupply of the subsidized item. 37. Explicit price subsidies are recorded in the government budget as expenditures, although not necessarily under the category “subsidies.”15 Explicit subsidies can take many forms. In the case of a consumer subsidy, a public agency can make direct payments to producers to compensate them for charging lower prices for their output. Alternatively, the government can directly provide goods and services free of charge or at below-market prices through a public distribution system. 38. Implicit price subsidies are not easily identifiable in the government budget, but can show up as (1) losses of the banking system (e.g., owing to below-market interest rates or directed credits); (2) losses of state-owned enterprises, owing to setting prices below cost recovery levels; (3) differential tariffs for various consumers (e.g., by charging industrial users a higher tariff for electricity and water); (4) tax expenditures (e.g., tax exemptions, concessions, and deferrals); (5) below-market procurement prices, which act as a tax on producers and a subsidy for consumers; (6) equity participation in state-owned enterprises without an expectation of a market return or net lending to them at preferential interest rates; (7) regulations that alter market prices or restrict market access (regulatory subsidies); and (8) distribution of donor-provided commodities at below-market prices. All these subsidies affect the government budget, although some (tax expenditures, equity participation, and net lending) more directly than others. 39. A price-subsidy policy can be helpful in pursuing social and economic goals. Price subsidies can be designed to correct market imperfections. For example, the provision of basic education and childhood immunizations free of charge or at reduced tariffs can promote broad-based human and economic development. Subsidies can also be used to address domestic market imperfections in domestic factor and product markets of traded goods. In that case, a subsidy policy is preferable to imposing tariffs (Bhagwati and Ramaswami, 1963). Other price subsidies, such as for basic commodities, can provide food security and improve the well-being of the lowest-income individuals and households in a society. Transitory subsidies may be the only means of cushioning against sharp losses of purchasing power (e.g., following the CFA franc zone exchange reform, and in the wake of the 1997 financial crisis in Indonesia). 40. In practice, price subsidies have also been motivated by other goals, including providing subsidies to nonpoor special interest groups (e.g., in 1999, only 21 percent of kerosene subsidies reached the poorest 30 percent of households in Indonesia). 41. Even when price subsidies achieve their intended objectives, their economic and social benefits have to be weighed against their costs:
|
|||||||||||||||||||||
Appendix 3: Examining the Short-Term Impact of Reducing Price Subsidies on Real Household Incomes: An Illustration | |||||||||||||||||||||
42. This appendix provides two competing pragmatic approaches to estimating the impact of price-subsidy reform on households in the short term.
43. Which estimate of real-income loss is more appropriate? The above approaches provide a reasonable range within which the correct answer is likely to fall. Which point in this range is most relevant for estimating the desirable level of compensation for price-subsidy reform depends on many factors, including whether the subsidized item is a basic commodity and some substitution possibilities exist. To be more precise, which estimate is more accurate depends on the size of the income effect of the price change versus the substitution effect. What is reassuring, however, is that the difference between the two estimates is typically small for poor households. In the above example, the estimates differ by only two percentage points. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
Index Guide to Concepts and Issues20 | |||||||||||||||||||||
Administrative capacity, 7, 14, 16, 23, 25, Box 1, and Table 1. Available financing, 7 and 26. Benefit incidence and equity, 19–20, 28, 31–32, 35, and 40. Cash transfers, 8–11, 15–16, 29, and Boxes 3–4. Delivery mechanism, 15, and Box 3. Exogenous factors, 29, 33, and Box 1. Efficiency of compensation mechanisms, 12–13 and 34. Fiscal savings, 1–2, 5–7, 26, 33, and Boxes 1–3. Mass information campaigns, 32, and 35. Middle class and other nonpoor groups, 7, 28–29, and 32. Political disruption, 28–32, and Box 4. Political support for price-subsidy reform, 6–7, 28–32, and Boxes 1 and 4. Price-subsidy reform in the longer term, 9, 32, and 34. Rationale for price-subsidy reform, 1, 4, 18, 20, and 41. Reversal of price-subsidy reform, 6–7, 33, and Box 1. Social impact and disruption, 2, 4–5, 20–21, and Boxes 1 and 3. Social safety nets and social compensation instruments, 5, 7–10, 15–16, 23, 25–26, 32, 34, Boxes 1–4, and Table 1. Speed of price-subsidy reform, 5–7, 33, and Box 1. Stakeholder approach, 32, 35, and Box 4. Subsidies by type,
Subsidies and environment, 27 and 41. Targeting, 8, 10–16, 25, 28, 34, Boxes 2–3, and Table 1. Targeting by type,
Winners and losers of price-subsidy reform, 29, 32, and Box 4. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
Footnotes: 1Before 1994, generalized subsidies in Jordan covered many food items at an average cost to the budget of 2.2 percent of GDP. These subsidies took two forms: (1) coupons distributed to all households for buying rice, sugar, and milk; and (2) wheat price controls, which provided an implicit subsidy for bread. In 1995, the government also began issuing coupons for bread, but the price of bread remained extremely low, leading to wasteful consumption (bread was used for animal feed) and smuggling. In 1996, the price of wheat was increased and the government replaced coupons with a cash transfer for bread. This also led to an increase in prices of other foods like poultry and dairy products, which provoked food riots. In 1999, the fall in international wheat prices offered the opportunity to align the domestic price with its international level and integrate cash transfers into the targeted social assistance programs administered by the National Aid Fund. But the authorities set the domestic price of bread somewhat below its production cost, and a small subsidy reappeared. The domestic price of wheat continues to be controlled, and the bread subsidies may rise if wheat import prices increase. 2In some instances, the government awarded wage increases at the time of price liberalization. This policy is tantamount to a cash compensation targeted to workers in the public sector and recipients of social security benefits. 3Korea has been successful in phasing out safety nets after the effects of the 1998 financial crisis dissipated. 4Based on a sample of 24 targeted-subsidy and cash-transfer programs in 11 countries in Latin America, Grosh (1994) finds that the administrative cost as a share of total program cost ranges from 3 percent to 10 percent for self-targeted programs, against 4 percent to 16 percent for geographically targeted programs, and !/2 percent to 29 percent for programs that assess eligibility individually for each participant. These wide differences in administrative cost are not reflected in the targeting efficiency; for all programs for which data were available, the share of benefits accruing to the poorest 40 percent was within or near the 70 percent to 75 percent range. This result can be attributed to the small share of screening cost of participants in the overall administrative cost of subsidy programs and disparity in the availability of existing mechanisms to channel benefits. Another reason might be that the administrative costs do not vary significantly with the level of the benefits; administration of a scheme that pays beneficiaries very little will thus tend to absorb a large share of the total program cost, independent of the targeting mechanism (see Foster, Goméz-Lobo, and Halpern, 2000). 5See also Van de Walle (1998). Several studies have shown that the targeting of social safety nets tends to become more efficient over time; see Hammer, Nabi, and Cercone (1995) and Lanjouw and Ravallion (1999). 6Targeted food supplements and nutrition interventions for women and children, including school feeding programs, are a special case of such targeting. The drawbacks of these programs are imperfect coverage of the poor and high administrative costs. On the other hand, they are not associated with labor market disincentive effects, and are subject to minimal leakage. 7In Zambia, where cash-for-work road construction projects offered a relatively high wage rate, some beneficiaries subcontracted their jobs to others at a lower wage. 8The principal factors that underlie self-targeting in the broader sense are the opportunity cost of time used for obtaining benefits in work programs, the attractiveness of products to the poor, and social stigma. 9In practice, the design of price-subsidy reforms will be the outcome of a collaborative process involving the country authorities, the IMF, the World Bank, and other stakeholders, particularly if such reforms are part of a poverty reduction strategy paper. 10If full information from existing sources is lacking, substantial resources would be required to take into account all relevant considerations set forth in the guide. 11For a number of countries, World Bank staff carries out analyses of the impact of price subsidies in the context of the Poverty Assessments and Public Expenditure Reviews. 12However, Pitt (1985) found that kerosene subsidies in Indonesia disproportionally benefited the nonpoor and that the elasticity of substitution between firewood and kerosene was very small. 13Hausmann (1994) argues that entitlements, such as subsidies, imply a negative-sum game leading to a highly inefficient but stable political (Nash) equilibrium. Moving to a better, Pareto-efficient equilibrium, requires a package of policies that yields benefits over the medium term for all groups. Ravallion and Lokshin (2000) examine support for government redistribution in the Russian Federation in 1996. They find that support for redistribution not only depends on whether the population is poor or well-off, but also on whether it expects to suffer an income loss or gain. 14An asterisk indicates that data on public spending on price subsidies before and after reform are available for the country. 15Subsidies paid to consumers, as opposed to producers, are typically classified as transfers in the public sector accounts. Subsidies that are administered by extrabudgetary funds (such as agricultural subsidies in a number of countries) are sometimes not consolidated with the budget. 16Data on subsidies are from the United Nation’s System of National Accounts (SNA), which defines subsidies as current unrequited government payments to enterprises on the basis of their production, sales, or imports. Thus, the SNA data on subsidies exclude payments to consumers, such as food stamps, which are recorded under transfers, as well as implicit subsidies. The IMF’s Government Finance Statistics (GFS) uses a similar definition of subsidies as the SNA; however, for most countries, the GFS does not report separately on subsidy payments but instead lumps these outlays together with government transfers. 17Clements, Rodríguez, and Schwartz (1998) find that a large government, a large external current account deficit, and a relatively large manufacturing sector are associated with a higher level of explicit subsidies. 18Data on household expenditures can be obtained from household surveys. 19The estimate reflects households who respond to price changes in such a way that the shares of spending on different consumption items in their total expenditures remains constant. This behavior is consistent with preferences that can be described by (a monotonic transformation of) a Cobb Douglas function, which has unitary compensated own-price and cross-price elasticities. Preferences of this type also underlie calculation of the Consumer Price Index in a number of countries, including many components of the CPI for the United States. |
|||||||||||||||||||||
References | |||||||||||||||||||||
Alderman, Harold, and Kathy Lindert, 1998, “The Potential and Limitations of Self-Targeted Food Subsidies,” The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 13 (August), pp. 213–29. Ĺslund, Anders, Peter Boone, and Simon Johnson, 1996, “How to Stabilize: Lessons from Post-Communist Countries,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1 (Washington: Brookings Institution), pp. 217–91. Bhagwati, Jagdish, and V.K. Ramaswami, 1963, “Domestic Distortions, Tariffs and the Theory of Optimum Subsidy,” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 71 (February), pp. 44–50. Chu, Ke-young, and others, 1995, Unproductive Public Expenditures: A Pragmatic Approach to Policy Analysis, IMF Pamphlet Series No. 48 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Chu, Ke-young, and Sanjeev Gupta, 1998a, “Economic Reforms, Social Safety Nets, and the Budget in Transition Economies,” in Social Safety Nets: Issues and Recent Experiences, ed. by Ke-young Chu and Sanjeev Gupta (Washington: International Monetary Fund). ———, 1998b, “Social Safety Nets in Economic Reform,” in Social Safety Nets: Issues and Recent Experiences, ed. by Ke-young Chu and Sanjeev Gupta (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Chu, Ke-young, Hamid Davoodi, and Sanjeev Gupta, 2000, “Income Distribution and Tax and Government Social Spending Policies in Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper 00/62 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Clements, Benedict, Hugo Rodríguez, and Gerd Schwartz, 1998, “Economic Determinants of Government Subsidies,” IMF Working Paper 98/166 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Davis, Shelton H., 1977, Victims of the Miracle: Development Against the Indians of Brazil (New York: Cambridge University Press). Deaton, Angus, 1997, The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy (Washington: World Bank). De Donder, Philippe, and Jean Hindriks, 1998, “The Political Economy of Targeting,” Public Choice, Vol. 95 (April), pp. 177–200. Demery, Lionel, 1999, “Poverty Dynamics in Africa: An Update” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank). Edirisinghe, Neville, 1988, “Recent Targeting Attempts in Sri Lanka’s Food Stamp Scheme,” Food Policy, Vol. 13 (November), pp. 401–02. Foster, Vivien, Andrés Goméz-Lobo, and Jonathan Halpern, 2000, “Designing Direct Subsidies for Water and Sanitation Services—Panama: A Case Study,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 2344 (Washington: World Bank). Freund, Caroline, and Christine Wallich, 1997, “Public-Sector Price Reforms in Transition Economies: Who Gains? Who Loses? The Case of Household Energy Prices in Poland,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 46 (October), pp. 35–59. Gelbach, Jonah, and Lant Pritchett, forthcoming, “Indicator Targeting in a Political Economy Can Be Better,” Journal of Policy Reform. Graham, Carol, 1994, Safety Nets, Politics, and the Poor: Transitions to Market Economies (Washington: Brookings Institution). ———, 1998, Private Markets for Public Goods: Raising the Stakes in Economic Reform (Washington: Brookings Institution). Grootaert, Christiaan, and Jeanine Braithwaite, 1998, “Poverty Correlates and Indicator-Based Targeting in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1942 (Washington: World Bank). Grosh, Margaret, 1994, Administering Targeted Social Programs in Latin America: From Platitudes to Practice, World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies (Washington: World Bank). Gupta, Sanjeev, Kenneth M. Miranda, and Ian Parry, 1995, “Public Expenditure Policy and the Environment: A Review and Synthesis,” World Development, Vol. 23 (March), pp. 515–28. Gupta, Sanjeev, and others, 1999, “Mitigating the Social Costs of the Economic Crisis and the Reform Programs in Asia,” International Economic Policy Review, Vol. 1, pp. 91–110. Hammer, Jeffrey S., Ijaz Nabi, and James A. Cercone, 1995, “Distributional Effects of Social Sector Expenditures in Malaysia, 1974–89,” in Public Spending and the Poor: Theory and Evidence, ed. by Dominique Van de Walle and Kimberly Nead (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press). Hausmann, Ricardo, 1994, “Sustaining Reform: What Role for Social Policy?” in Redefining the State in Latin America, ed. by Colin I. Bradford, Jr. (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development). ———, 1998, “Comments,” in Income Distribution and High-Quality Growth, ed. by Vito Tanzi and Ke-young Chu (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press). Hu, Zu-liu, 1998, “Social Protection, Labor Market Rigidity, and Enterprise Restructuring in China,” in Social Safety Nets: Issues and Recent Experiences, ed. by Ke-young Chu and Sanjeev Gupta (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Lanjouw, Peter, and Martin Ravallion, 1999, “Benefit Incidence, Public Spending Reforms, and the Timing of Program Capture,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 13 (May), pp. 257–73. Moser, Gary, Scott Rogers, and Reinold van Til, 1997, Nigeria: Experience with Structural Adjustment, IMF Occasional Paper No. 148 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Naim, Moises, 1993, “Good Economics and Ugly Politics: The Venezuelan Reforms,” International Economic Insights, Vol. 4 (July/August), pp. 45–48. Nelson, Joan M., and others, 1994, Intricate Links: Democratization and Market Reforms in Latin America and Eastern Europe (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers). Pitt, Mark M., 1985, “Equity, Externalities and Energy Subsidies: The Case of Kerosene in Indonesia,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 17 (April), pp. 201–17. Radhakrishna, R., and others, 1997, “India’s Public Distribution System: A National and International Perspective,” World Bank Discussion Paper No. 380 (Washington: World Bank). Ravallion, Martin, and Michael Lokshin, 2000, “Who Wants to Redistribute? The Tunnel Effect in 1990s Russia,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76 (April), pp. 87–104. Razmara, Setareh, and others, 1999, “Consumer Food Subsidy Programs in Middle East and North Africa,” draft, Report No. 19561-MNA (Washington: World Bank). Rosenblatt, Julius, and others, 1988, The Common Agricultural Policy of the European Community: Principles and Consequences, IMF Occasional Paper No. 62 (Washington: International Monetary Fund). Samuelson, Robert J., 1995, The Good Life and Its Discontents (New York: Random House). Schwartz, Gerd, and Benedict Clements, 1999, “Government Subsidies,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 13 (April), pp. 119–47. Thorbecke, Willem, 1998, “The Economic Crisis in Indonesia: Social Costs and Policy Implications,” Office of Development Studies Working Paper No. 7 (New York: United Nations Development Programme). Van de Walle, Dominique, 1998, “Targeting Revisited,” The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 13 (August), pp. 231–48. Warner, Andrew M., 1997, “Is Economic Reform Popular at the Polls?” Development Discussion Paper No. 598 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Institute for International Development). |