Executive SummaryThis paper follows up on two earlier Board discussions about the financial terms—charges and repurchase periods—and eligibility requirements of “core” Fund facilities, namely, stand-by arrangements, the Extended Fund Facility (EFF), the Supplemental Reserve Facility (SRF), and the Contingent Credit Lines (CCL). The paper also considers further certain features of post-program monitoring. Terms of stand-by arrangements and the EFF With the globalization of capital markets, concerns have been voiced that some members may be making excessive use of Fund resources—either unduly long or unduly large use. Although concerns about long and large use are interrelated, the following aspects of undue use could be distinguished:
There are a number of instruments the Fund could use to try to counter undue use of its resources:
Any changes in the terms of Fund financing—introduction of REs, or graduation of charges—should apply only to new purchases. Credit outstanding at the time of adoption of the policy changes would not be affected. The impact on Fund income and on members of the changes under consideration is extremely hard to predict, in large part because members’ response to the policy changes cannot be known in advance. Illustrative calculations suggest that the impact on Fund income could range from strongly negative to strongly positive, and that the effects on individual members would be modest. The Contingent Credit Lines There is a strong case for reducing the Fund’s discretion to require policy changes in the CCL activation review—in effect separating the “activation” review (which would be held expeditiously and would make available a predetermined, large amount of resources) from a “post-activation” review (which would be held immediately following in-depth discussions between the member and the staff regarding the possible need for policy adjustments). As regards whether a crisis is traceable to contagion, the staff believes that it would be useful to include, in a member’s request for a commitment of CCL resources, an illustrative list of situations in which the CCL might be activated. With regard to the other conditions for completion of the activation review—the existence of a crisis, and the member’s adherence to its program to date—the staff sees little opportunity to reduce the scope for judgment on the Fund’s part, but believes that these conditions introduce only limited uncertainty for the member. There remain questions as to how a member might exit from the CCL—because of policy slippages or other reasons—without risking disturbing markets, and, correspondingly, whether the Fund might be reluctant to force a member to exit in the event of slippages. In this regard, precautionary arrangements are an attractive avenue for exit, but a member cannot be compelled to request an arrangement. A “graduated response” in the form, for instance, of a reduction in the amount available on completion of the activation review would bring with it the risk of a multi-tiered CCL, and of a loss of credibility. At the same time, exit may itself take place gradually rather than suddenly, as the prospects for completion of a mid-term review or approval of a new commitment under the CCL gradually dim with time. There is broad agreement that the rate of charge on the CCL should be reduced, in particular so that it is below the rate on the SRF. It may be reasonable to halve the initial surcharge to 150 basis points (that is, 150 basis points below the initial SRF surcharge), but to keep its graduation with time unchanged, until the surcharge reaches a level of 350 basis points (again, 150 basis points below the ceiling on the SRF surcharge). There is also broad agreement that the commitment fee should be reduced or eliminated. The mechanism for such a reduction would be a change in the Fund’s Rules and Regulations, that would make the commitment fee apply—for all arrangements—to the amounts scheduled for the next twelve months. Such a change would virtually eliminate the commitment fee under the CCL. The Extended Fund Facility There is widespread agreement that greater attention should be given to ensuring that access to the EFF is granted only in cases where the member’s balance of payments difficulties are expected to be relatively long-term. As a result, the EFF would probably not be used by members with well-established access to capital markets. There is also widespread agreement that use of the EFF on a precautionary basis should be exceptional, as there will rarely if ever be a high likelihood that a member without an immediate balance of payments problem would develop longer-term balance of payments difficulties. Post-program monitoring Stronger post-program monitoring (PPM) would provide for closer monitoring of the circumstances and policies of members whose arrangements have ended but that continue to have Fund resources outstanding. Such monitoring would be regular (at six-monthly intervals) and would involve staff discussions with the member, reported by means of a staff paper and discussed by the Board. Such PPM could be based on the existing consultation clauses in all arrangements. It would be possible to adopt stronger procedures for PPM without adopting automatic criteria for it. PPM could be based on the recommendation of the Managing Director, and the agreement of the Board, on the occasion of a member’s Article IV consultation or during informal country matters sessions. At the same time, there may be a case for automatic application of PPM, or for a presumption of application, if certain criteria are met (for instance, relating to the level of Fund credit outstanding in relation to quota), as ad hoc procedures tend to be little used. |
I. Introduction1. The Executive Board has been conducting a comprehensive review of the Fund’s nonconcessional financing facilities, with discussions in March and July 2000.1 2. Notwithstanding a rather wide consensus on the nature of the Fund’s financing role in a changing global environment, the July discussion brought to the surface considerable differences of opinion as to specific changes that may be required in the Fund’s core facilities.2 While there was broad agreement on the general direction of the changes needed to the Contingent Credit Lines (CCL) and on the eligibility requirements under the Extended Fund Facility (EFF), there were much greater divergences of view as regards possible changes to repurchase periods and rates of charge (for stand-by arrangements and the EFF) and as regards post-program monitoring. 3. The present paper seeks to follow up on these issues. In large part, it represents a stocktaking of the analysis presented in RoF I and RoF II, in the light of the views expressed by Directors at the last meeting. Its discussion should help clarify what the next steps in the process should be, including if possible a timeframe for moving to decisions. 4. The paper is structured as follows: Chapter II considers repurchase periods and charges; Chapter III, the CCL; Chapter IV, the eligibility requirements under the EFF; and Chapter V, post-program monitoring. Chapter VI suggests issues for discussion. |
II. Repurchase Periods and Charges5. The Board has had a lively discussion about whether the terms of the Fund’s core facilities—stand-by arrangements and the EFF in particular—remain appropriate in an environment of increasingly globalized capital markets. With many—though still by no means all—members able to access capital markets, questions arise as to whether repurchase periods and charges are well-tailored to encourage members to seek to use, restore, or establish such access to private financing, or whether they encourage members to rely excessively on Fund resources. 6. An important theme of this discussion has been “whether there is a problem.” In particular, with how much concern should the Fund be viewing long or large use of its resources? And are members indeed making unduly long or large use of the Fund’s resources? 7. In order to address these questions, it is useful to distinguish three aspects of the possibility that members may be making excessive use of Fund resources. Two relate to the possibility of unduly long use of Fund resources—where “use” can be interpreted either as the drawing of Fund resources or as the nonrepayment of Fund resources at the earliest opportunity. The third relates to the possibility of unduly large use of Fund resources. These three aspects are, of course, interrelated: the Fund is likely to be significantly more concerned about long use of a large amount of its resources than of a small amount. Nonetheless, the three aspects provide a useful broad taxonomy of the issue, and the following paragraphs consider each of them separately, examining in turn the appropriate degree of Fund concern and the likely prevalence of the phenomenon. 8. The first aspect of unduly long use of Fund resources may arise when members draw Fund resources over a series of arrangements. This phenomenon is traditionally known in the Fund as “prolonged use:”3
9. The second aspect of unduly long use of Fund resources arises when a member has credit outstanding for an unduly long time following the resolution of a balance of payments problem. Questions about this phenomenon revolve around whether members might be able to repay sooner than is specified in the 5- or 10-year repurchase schedules of stand-by and extended arrangements, respectively:
10. Finally, the possibility exists that members are making unduly large use of the Fund’s resources:
11. If long and/or large use are problems to be addressed, then the question arises which instruments could best be used to address them. A number of instruments/options affecting the terms of Fund financing are candidates in this respect:
12. The next two sections discuss, respectively, the instruments available to address long use and large use. The sections also evaluate the impact of each of these instruments on individual members and on the Fund’s income. As noted above, under “long use” the focus is on long use following resolution of a balance of payments problem, rather than prolonged use over a series of arrangements (which is instead captured, to some extent, under large use). 13. Any changes to the facilities would be forward looking, and members should not bear an additional financial burden for decisions made to date.20 In this light, it would seem reasonable to apply possible changes in charges and repurchase expectations only to purchases that take place after the effective date of the decision. All such purchases, including those pursuant to arrangements approved prior to that date, would be subject to those changes. In any event, the membership as a whole would not face the full effect of the changes for a number of years, and the full impact on the Fund’s net income would not be apparent for some time. 14. Like the previous papers, the present paper treats stand-by arrangements as one of the Fund’s core facilities (see footnote 2), even though SBAs are not strictly speaking a facility. SBAs are a means for members to access the credit tranches, and can also be used to deliver other types of resources (e.g., SRF or CCL resources, which are provided under stand-by arrangements in combination with credit tranche resources). The paper uses the term SBA, for presentational simplicity, to denote a stand-by arrangement in the upper credit tranches. Any changes that the Fund wishes to make to SBAs (e.g., introduction of repurchase expectations or graduation of charges) would actually need to be made to the credit tranches. 15. The non-core facilities in the credit tranches would be automatically affected by the changes discussed below—but, if it were desired, it would be possible in many cases to prevent such consequential changes. Any changes introduced with a view mainly to affecting stand-by arrangements would affect other policies in the credit tranches—namely, the first credit tranche and emergency assistance for natural disasters and post-conflict cases. In some cases, this would not make a difference in practice; for instance, graduation of charges with the level of credit outstanding would not affect the first credit tranche, as long as graduation did not start below 25 percent of quota.21 In the case of the two forms of emergency assistance, any changes could be prevented by turning these into special policies (which would require a 70-85 percent majority of the total voting power, depending on the features of the special policies).22 The Compensatory Financing Facility (CFF) is not part of the credit tranches, and would not be automatically affected by most of the changes discussed in this paper. However, should the Fund make changes to the terms of the credit tranches and the EFF, it might want to consider making similar changes to the CFF, so as not to bias members toward use of the latter facility. A. Addressing Long Use16. As noted above, there are three instruments that can address the problem of long use: the early repurchase policy, time-based repurchase expectations, and graduation of charges with time. The present section will discuss first the early repurchase policy and then, together, time-based repurchase expectations and graduation of charges with time. (i) The early repurchase policy 17. Under existing policies, the Fund’s primary instrument to address long use of Fund resources following the resolution of a balance of payments problem is the early repurchase policy (ERP), and it is natural to ask why, if there is a problem of long use, this policy does not achieve its objectives. The answer this section will give is that the ERP is flawed in ways that, if remedied, would make it closely resemble time-based repurchase expectations. The functioning of the ERP is described in Box 1 (which reproduces Annex III of RoF I). 18. Experience shows that the ERP has not worked well, especially recently. Any measure of the overall effectiveness of the ERP must take at least some account of voluntary advance repurchases, since members may be encouraged to make advance repurchases by the prospect that early repurchase expectations could be imposed (Table 1).23 However, even taken together, the number of members making early or (voluntary) advance repurchases is consistently small relative to the number of members with Fund credit outstanding, and is certainly not commensurate with the substantial proportion of members found to experience a rapid turnaround in their balance of payments following an arrangement (as examined in RoF II). Moreover, the number of members making early and advance repurchases has fallen since the 1980s (as has the number of early and advance repurchases), with the decline in early repurchases especially marked; no early repurchase expectation has been imposed under the ERP since 1994.24 |
Early Repurchases 2/ |
Advance Repurchases |
Total | |||||
Total number of transactions |
|||||||
1983–1990 | 33 | 16 | 49 | ||||
1991–2000 | 5 | 12 | 3/ | 17 | |||
Total number of members | |||||||
1983–1990 | 9 | 13 | 22 | ||||
1991–2000 | 2 | 7 | 3/ | 9 | |||
Total amount (in millions of SDRs) |
|||||||
1983–1990 | 1,745 | 1,038 | 2,783 | ||||
1991–2000 | 92 | 5,621 | 3/ | 5,713 | |||
Number of members per year in percent of number of members with credit outstanding at the end of previous year (period average) |
|||||||
1983–1990 | 2.8 | 2.3 | 5.0 | ||||
1991–2000 | 0.3 | 1.6 | 3/ | 1.9 | |||
Amount per year in percent of credit outstanding at the end of the previous year (period average) |
|||||||
1983–1990 | 1.0 | 0.5 | 1.4 | ||||
1991–2000 | 0.1 | 1.8 | 3/ | 1.9 | |||
1/ Excluding SRF resources. Historical data on early repurchases are maintained on an annual basis (June-May) that differs slightly from the Fund’s financial year (May-April). |
Box 1. Early Repurchases Under Article V, Section 7(b) Identifying members to repurchase early Early repurchase expectations are established in the context of an assessment of the balance of payments and reserve position of members for the purposes of inclusion in the financial transactions plan (formerly called the operational budget) and the designation plan.1 Specific indicators of external strength are used in this assessment to maintain a degree of consistency among members, but the strength of a member’s external position is ultimately a matter of judgment. All relevant factors and data are considered, with particular emphasis on recent and prospective current account balances, competitiveness, and external debt indicators, especially those offering insights into the member’s exposure to short-term liquidity strains. For members with outstanding use of Fund resources (“debtor members”), judgments must also be made on whether the external position has improved relative to the time of the last purchase, and on the extent and sustainability of the improvement.2 Members are not expected to repurchase early until the quarter following the second full quarter after their last purchase. Calculating the repurchase amount The formula for calculating the early repurchase amount is driven by gross reserves—1.5 percent of reserves plus or minus 5 percent of the change in reserves over the most recent six months, subject to the constraints that this amount cannot exceed 4 percent of reserves in a quarter, or 10 percent of reserves over a year, and cannot reduce reserves below 250 percent of quota. Meeting an expectation Early repurchase expectations can be reduced, or extinguished altogether, to the extent that scheduled repurchases fall due during the quarter or the member has made advance repurchases; credit for advance repurchases lapses after five quarters. The remaining expectation can be met either through repurchases or through the use of the member’s currency in transfers in the financial transactions plan. Sanctions There are no sanctions prescribed for failure to meet an early repurchase expectation. The Articles foresee that, if a member failed to meet an early repurchase expectation, and after consultation with the member, the Fund could make a representation to the member to repurchase, which would convert the expectation into an obligation. (The Fund has not, however, adopted a policy to give effect to this.) Failure to meet a repurchase obligation would expose the member to a range of sanctions by the Fund, including ineligibility to use the general resources of the Fund, suspension of voting rights, and withdrawal from membership. 1Decision No. 6172-(79/101), June 28, 1979, Selected Decisions, pages 319-321. |
19. The main problems with the early repurchase policy are the following:
20. The staff believes that remedying the flaws in the ERP would essentially replicate the time-based repurchase expectations (REs) proposed in RoF II:
21. The staff thus believes that, among instruments relying on rules rather than incentives, time-based repurchase expectations stand the best chance of ensuring that members repay as their external position improves. Such repurchase expectations would be included in all arrangements and would complement the existing ERP, which could continue to play a useful role for the exceptional situations where countries’ positions improved so rapidly that they were able to repay before the dates specified in the expectation schedules. The staff could return at a later date to the issue of strengthening the early repurchase policy (which, as noted above, is likely to involve reconfiguring the policy to resemble more closely, and to the extent possible, time-based repurchase expectations). (ii) Graduation of charges with time and repurchase expectations 22. Graduation of charges with time and time-based repurchase expectations can be seen as two alternative ways of addressing the problem of long use, with the emphasis placed, respectively, on quantitative rules and on incentives. 23. At the same time, it is not clear that time-based graduation of charges and repurchase expectations would be suitable complements. If both instruments were used at the same time, weaker members, which had been found not able to adhere to the repurchase expectation schedule, would have to pay a surcharge.28 Whether this was deemed appropriate would depend on the degree to which the weakness of such members’ external positions was considered to reflect a weakness in policies, rather than exogenous constraints. 24. The present section will discuss in turn options for graduation of charges with time and for time-based repurchase expectations, and will then provide tentative estimates of the possible impact of these policies on members and on the Fund, with the aim of eliciting Directors’ views on which of these changes, if any, they might support. Graduation of charges with time 25. A price incentive to encourage advance repurchases could be introduced as a surcharge graduated with the length of time that credit has been outstanding.29 Such a surcharge could begin at a low rate, starting, for example, at the time when repurchases begin to fall due—after 3¼ years for SBAs and after 4½ years for extended arrangements. In recognition of the longer maturities of the EFF, the surcharge under an EA could rise more gradually than under an SBA (see Figure 1 for two possible options). 26. A surcharge that graduates with the time credit has been outstanding could begin, in principle, either from the date of each purchase, or from the date of the first purchase under an arrangement. The former would be feasible within the present structure of facilities, but the latter would require important changes in that structure. As noted in paragraph 15, at present SBAs are but one means of accessing the credit tranches: other means comprise outright purchases under emergency assistance, as well as other outright purchases in the credit tranches (although there have been none of the latter since 1968). Because the concept of “first purchase under the arrangement” is meaningless for outright purchases, and because the principle of uniformity of treatment dictates that purchases under arrangements in the credit tranches must be treated the same way as outright purchases in the credit tranches, graduation with time in the present structure would have to begin separately for each purchase from the date of that purchase. To make feasible graduation with time from the date of the first purchase for all amounts drawn under an arrangement, stand-by arrangements would have to be made the only means of accessing the credit tranches—implying that (i) the two forms of emergency assistance would have to be turned into special policies, (ii) the possibility of other outright purchases in the credit tranches would have to be terminated, and (iii) the Board would have to agree that credit tranche purchases through SBAs would constitute the general policy on access to the Fund’s general resources (i.e., available for all types of balance of payments problems) that the Fund is required to have according to Article V, Section 3(a). These changes would require a 70-85 percent majority of the total voting power, depending on the features of the special policies thus created on emergency assistance (see footnote 22). |
Option T1 |
---|
Option T2 |
27. A time-based surcharge would have both advantages and disadvantages:
Time-based repurchase expectations 28. Introducing time-based repurchase expectations could give the Fund a flexible instrument to address directly unduly long use of Fund resources. Repurchase expectations would consist of a repurchase schedule with earlier repayment dates than the dates in the obligations schedule. 29. A member would be expected to meet the earlier schedule of repurchases, but a member whose external position does not allow it to meet repurchase expectations could request the Fund to grant it a waiver of the expectation. The member would request such a waiver in advance of the repurchase expectation date. If a waiver were not granted and the expectation were not met, remedies would apply (see below). The member could request a waiver at any time—including, for instance, after it has met several repurchase expectations, should its external position deteriorate. The Fund could grant a waiver for several or all repurchase expectations at once. 30. Remedies would apply if the member did not adhere to the repurchase expectation schedule and a waiver had not been granted. In particular, the member’s right to make further purchases, including under ongoing arrangements, would be suspended.31 This remedy would be stronger than under the ERP, where no remedies are currently provided for—yet, even in the absence of remedies, no member has failed to meet any of the 38 early repurchase expectations imposed under the ERP in the 22 years since the Guidelines were established. In addition, consideration could be given to establishing a policy that would allow unmet REs to be converted into obligations (as under the SRF and CCL); failure to meet this obligation would then leave the member in arrears. Allowing the conversion of repurchase expectations into obligations would raise the majority required for the introduction of REs from a simple majority of the votes cast to an 85 percent majority of the total voting power.32 31. The Fund could establish criteria to guide its decisions as to whether to grant waivers of the expectations. Possible criteria are presented in Box 2 for preliminary consideration by Directors.33 32. It is important to note that the proposed time-based REs could constitute a means to encourage early repurchases when a member’s external position is strong, but would not be an instrument with which to induce early repurchases when the member’s policies are weak. As noted in RoF II (paragraph 50), under this approach, the Fund would not refuse a member’s request for a waiver of the expectation if its external position was weak as a consequence of its own policies. In this respect, a system with REs would resemble the current system, where members are permitted to continue to use Fund resources (in the sense of not repurchasing them) following the expiration of an arrangement, regardless of developments in their policies. The Fund could instead seek to influence the conduct of policies following an arrangement by means of post-program monitoring, which is discussed in Chapter V. 33. Consideration could be given to introducing REs into SBAs that bring the maturity structure forward by one year, as with the SRF and CCL. Repurchase periods would thus be advanced to 2¼ - 4 years from 3¼ - 5 years (Box 3).34 As noted in RoF II (paragraph 53), such a change would not necessarily be inconsistent with the maximum duration of SBAs of 3 years, since long SBAs are normally expected to turn precautionary in their later years, and, were this not the case, the member could request the Fund to grant a waiver of the expectation. |
Box 2. Criteria for Waiving Repurchase Expectations If time-based repurchase expectations were adopted, the granting of a waiver should hinge on an assessment of the member’s external position. In particular, the Board would have to agree with the member that the member’s external position was not sufficiently strong to permit early repurchases. If these criteria were met, the Fund would grant a waiver of the repurchase expectation. In practice, judgments on the strength of the external position would be based on a range of indicators, taking into account all relevant information: (i) foreign reserves, including in relation to imports and short-term debt; (ii) medium-term balance of payments (BOP) outlook under sound economic policies; and (iii) access to international capital markets, as reflected, inter alia, in trends in sovereign spreads and sovereign credit ratings. A member’s overall position would be considered, because repurchase expectations may be justified even if some elements of the external position are not strong. Early repayments of other credit would be one indicator of strength in the external position. If a member had made voluntary early repayments during the period since the outset of the arrangement on other official or commercial external debt, foreign reserves would be lower than otherwise. Nevertheless, these early repayments provide prima facie evidence that a member has confidence in the strength of its BOP position and in the reliability of its access to capital markets, such that it could also meet an early repurchase schedule pertaining to the Fund. In reaching judgments on repurchase expectations, special factors affecting the external position of each member should be taken into account, and appropriate safeguards should be applied to ensure that undue hardship or risks are not imposed on members. The strength of the external position would need to be evaluated bearing in mind factors including the member’s foreign exchange regime, exposure to external shocks (including commodity prices), foreign debt, and foreign exchange liquidity exposure. For example, a member with a currency board arrangement may need higher reserves than otherwise. If a waiver is to be refused, the medium-term BOP projection incorporating the proposed early repurchase schedule and based on sound policies (including debt and reserve management policies) should not involve the member bearing undue hardship or risks. |
34. Consideration could be given to introducing REs into the EFF that accelerate repayments after the grace period, by doubling repurchases until all credit is repaid. Purchases under the EFF carry repurchase periods of up to 10 years, including the grace period of 4½ years; REs could shorten the repurchase period from 10 to 7 years (Box 3). As noted in RoF II (paragraph 52), it may not be appropriate to shorten the grace period under the EFF in view of the need for members with EAs to undertake deep-seated reforms for several years. |
Box 3. Illustrative Repurchase Expectations Panel 1: Cycle of Credit for an SBA
Panel 1a: Schedule of Repurchases
Panel 2: Cycle of Credit for an EFF
Panel 2a: Schedule of Repurchases
These figures illustrate how repurchase expectations could be implemented: for SBAs, the repurchase schedule is advanced one year ahead of the standard schedule, so that repurchases begin after 2 ¼ years and each purchase is extinguished within 4 years, rather than the 5 years under the standard schedule; for EFFs, the grace period is unchanged but the repurchase period (including the grace period) is reduced from 10 to 7 years, thus leading to larger annual repurchases in earlier years. |
35. Both time-based repurchase expectations and time-based surcharges would apply only to purchases made after the changes came into effect, including purchases under arrangements already in existence at that time. If a surcharge schedule for time-based surcharges were to key off the first purchase under an arrangement, the Board would need to decide whether the first purchase under an existing arrangement made after the changes would be treated as “the first purchase under an arrangement.” Impact on Fund income and on members 36. The policy options described above would clearly have impacts on both individual members and on the Fund’s net income, but their effects cannot be predicted with confidence. Any quantitative exercise assessing the impacts of the changes on individual members and on Fund income must, by necessity, be based on certain assumptions, about both members’ responses to surcharges and the impact of repurchase expectations. In effect, any quantitative assessment will have to anticipate behavioral reactions about which very little is known. 37. A particular difficulty lies in estimating the changes in total Fund credit outstanding that might result from the policy changes, and any analysis has to make simplifying assumptions in this respect. Both surcharges and the establishment of REs would serve to decrease outstanding Fund credit from what it would otherwise be. The impact on the Fund’s income (and on total charges paid by members) will therefore reflect both the increase in charges and the decrease in credit outstanding. The net effect, however, cannot easily be estimated ex ante or ascertained ex post. Indeed, it is entirely possible that the Fund’s net income would decline. Moreover, because surcharges and repurchase expectations would apply only to new purchases, the impact on the Fund’s net income will be felt only some time in the future. Nevertheless, to make some headway, the staff has made simplifying assumptions (described below) to gauge the impact of the changes: assuming there are no behavioral reactions, and assuming an acceleration of repurchases in response to the introduction of surcharges. The following results should be viewed in light of the caveats described above. 38. REs by themselves would likely entail a loss of net income for the Fund, as they would lead to a reduction in the average amount of Fund credit outstanding compared to what it would have been without such expectations. Assuming that about half of members with arrangements would have been in a position to meet repurchase expectations, Fund credit would have been reduced by about 10 percent, based on illustrative repurchase expectations for SBAs and EAs (Box 3). Under this scenario, Fund credit would have been SDR 4.3 billion lower at end-June 2000 than it actually was. Such a reduction would have entailed a reduction in net Fund income on an annual basis of about SDR 30 million.35 39. By contrast, time-based surcharges could possibly generate additional net Fund income, particularly—an extreme assumption—should members not advance repurchases in response to the surcharges. With illustrative surcharges, based on the date of the first purchase under an arrangement, beginning to apply after the end of the grace period, a maximum amount of net income on the order of SDR 120-235 million could be generated on the basis of Fund credit outstanding at end-June 2000 (Tables 2 and 3).36 This assumes that members would not make any advance repurchases in response to the surcharge (i.e., the elasticity of repurchases with respect to surcharges is assumed to be zero). 40. When members respond to the surcharges by advancing repurchases, the net income gain to the Fund would be much smaller, because fewer surcharges are paid and the Fund loses net income at the regular rate of charge on the repurchases made in advance of when they were due. To illustrate the sensitivity of the calculated income gains to the repurchase behavior of members faced with a time-based surcharge, an alternative calculation (Table 3) assumes that members would reduce their average use of Fund credit by 10 percent as a result of the incentive effect of the surcharge. Members are assumed to advance the repurchases on their purchases subject to the highest surcharges. The illustrative gain in net income in this case would be about SDR 35-105 million, much smaller than that in the “zero elasticity” scenario. A stronger advance repurchase response by members than the assumed reduction in use of Fund credit by 10 percent could actually lead to net income losses for the Fund. 41. The impact on individual members faced with a time-based surcharge would in general be relatively modest. The impact can be illustrated by the additional charges members would pay relative to regular charges, or as an equivalent annual average surcharge (Table 4). The two illustrative options for a time-based surcharge would raise total charges paid by members under “typical” SBAs by 5 - 10 percent, and 8 - 16 percent under “typical” EAs, assuming that members did not make advance repurchases in response to the surcharges (the “zero elasticity” scenario). Were members to reduce their use of Fund credit by 10 percent over the course of the arrangement by advancing their repurchases subject to the highest surcharges, their surcharge payments would be reduced by about a third compared to the zero elasticity scenario.37 |
Table 2. Fund Credit by Time Elapsed since First Purchase, End-June 2000 1/ | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(In millions of SDRs) | ||||||
Stand-by 2/ | EFF 3/ | Total | ||||
Up to 1 year | 3,508 | 542 | 4,050 | |||
Between 1 and 2 years | 5,061 | 4,950 | 10,011 | |||
Between 2 and 3 years | 10,946 | 194 | 11,140 | |||
Between 3 and 4 years | 834 | 243 | 1,077 | |||
Between 4 and 5 years | 1,284 | 5,442 | 6,726 | |||
Between 5 and 6 years | 1,423 | 1,973 | 3,396 | |||
Between 6 and 7 years | -- | 2,850 | 2,850 | |||
Between 7 and 8 years | -- | 499 | 499 | |||
Between 8 and 9 years | -- | 2,327 | 2,327 | |||
Between 9 and 10 years | -- | 40 | 40 | |||
Over 10 years | -- | 136 | 136 | |||
Total | 23,056 | 19,196 | 42,252 | |||
1/ Excluding overdue credit. |
Illustrative Impact on Fund’s Annual Net Income 1/ |
||||
Zero Elasticity of Repurchases with Respect to Surcharges |
Ten Percent Reduction in Average Use of Fund Credit 2/ |
Number of Members Paying Surcharge 3/ |
||
(In millions of SDRs) | ||||
Option T1 4/ | ||||
Stand-by 5/ | 38 | 18 | 24 | |
EFF 5/ | 80 | 18 | 31 | |
Total | 118 | 37 | 55 | 6/ |
Option T2 4/ | ||||
Stand-by 5/ | 76 | 43 | 24 | |
EFF 5/ | 160 | 60 | 31 | |
Total | 236 | 103 | 55 | 6/ |
1/ Based on data in Table 2, and assuming time-based surcharge on the basis of individual arrangements had always been in effect. Specifically, the calculations assume time-based surcharges had been applied to all outstanding GRA credit not in arrears. |
Surcharge Payments over Course of Typical Arrangement 1/ |
||||
Zero Elasticity of Repurchases with Respect to Surcharges |
Ten Percent Reduction in Average Use of Fund Credit 2/ |
|||
(In percent) | ||||
Option T1 3/ | ||||
Stand-by | ||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 5.2 | 3.1 | ||
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.28 | 0.17 | ||
EFF | ||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 7.9 | 5.3 | ||
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.43 | 0.29 | ||
Option T2 3/ | ||||
Stand-by | ||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 10.3 | 6.3 | ||
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.57 | 0.34 | ||
EFF | ||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 15.8 | 10.7 | ||
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.87 | 0.59 | ||
1/ See Box 3 for presentation of the terms of “typical” arrangements. |
B. Addressing Large Use42. As noted above, unduly large use of Fund resources can be seen as an issue separate from, though related to, the issue of unduly long use. While access policy would remain the Fund’s main instrument for curtailing large use, there is a case on this score for graduation of charges with the amount of credit outstanding. Such graduation would also help address the problem of prolonged use, to the extent that the Fund is concerned mostly about prolonged use of relatively large amounts of its resources. 43. The present section will describe various options for graduation of charges with amount, including some tentative estimates of the possible impact of these options on members and on the Fund, with a view to eliciting Directors’ views on which of these options, if any, they might support. Graduation of charges with the amount of credit outstanding 44. A surcharge graduated with the level of credit outstanding would provide members with an incentive to curtail large use. The SRF, which is designed to be used in circumstances where large use of Fund resources may be expected (above the annual access limit of 100 percent of quota or the cumulative access limit of 300 percent of quota), imposes a surcharge over the rate of charge beginning at 300 basis points. 45. A surcharge under SBAs and the EFF that peaks at 300 basis points would go some way toward harmonizing surcharges on the large use of GRA resources. Such a surcharge could be graduated, for example in three steps of 100 basis points, with the first step at outstanding credit of 100 percent of quota and additional steps as credit rises by each additional 100 percent of quota. Surcharges would apply to the corresponding marginal amounts of credit, not to the total amount of outstanding credit. Other options may be to exclude either the first or the first two steps (see Figure 2). However, a surcharge imposed only on amounts above 300 percent of credit outstanding would likely apply to very few members.38 A surcharge on amounts above 100 percent of quota would apply to rather more members, including “prolonged users” of Fund resources as these have usually been defined (see paragraph 8). |
Option L1 | |
---|---|
Option L2 | |
Option L3 |
46. Credit outstanding under the SRF and CCL would not be subject to the level-based surcharges being considered here. SRF resources would continue to carry their present surcharge over the basic rate of charge, of 300 basis points for the first year after the first purchase, and rising by 50 basis points every six months thereafter, up to a ceiling of 500 basis points. The surcharge on CCL resources—currently identical to that on SRF resources—is reconsidered below. 47. Level-based surcharges would apply to purchases made after the policy was introduced. Credit existing prior to the introduction of the policy would not bear a surcharge. However, such credit could be taken into account to determine which rate of surcharge applied to new drawings from the Fund, in which case a member with a large amount of Fund credit outstanding when the policy was introduced would pay a higher rate of charge on purchases under a new arrangement than would a member with little or no credit outstanding. Alternatively, credit outstanding when the policy was introduced could be excluded altogether from the determination of the surcharge, in which case it is likely to take some time before members’ new purchases cumulate to the levels where surcharges would apply. Impact on Fund income and on members 48. As noted above in the case of time-based surcharges, the impact of the introduction of a level-based surcharge on Fund income and on members is difficult to gauge. The impact depends on the amount of credit outstanding, the level of credit at which the surcharge begins to apply, the rate of surcharge, and how members would respond to the surcharge. For the purpose of illustrating the possible impacts on Fund income and on members, a level-based surcharge is assumed to be combined with REs (Table 5). While it would be possible to combine level-based and time-based surcharges, the combination would suffer from a number of drawbacks (see RoF II, paragraph 39). The illustrative REs discussed above were assumed to have reduced Fund credit at end-June 2000 by SDR 4.3 billion. 49. The impact of a level-based surcharge on net Fund income could range from strongly positive to strongly negative, depending on which scheme is assumed to be adopted and on members’ responses to it. Estimates of the impact of a level-based surcharge on net annual Fund income are based on the hypothetical distribution of Fund credit that is obtained after taking into account REs. If it is assumed that members did not advance their repurchases in response to the surcharge (“zero elasticity of repurchases with respect to surcharges”), the Fund might see a gain in its annual net income ranging up to SDR 180 million if graduation begins at credit of 100 percent of quota (Table 6).39 If the surcharge applies only at credit levels over 300 percent of quota, however, the net income gain would be small. If the opposite extreme assumption is made that members would advance their repurchases or forego purchases so as to avoid paying any surcharges (“infinite elasticity”), the Fund would stand to lose substantial net income due to the loss of regular net income on the advance repurchases or foregone purchases (which is added to the loss of income due to REs). How close to either extreme members’ behavioral response would actually be is not known. |
Amount 2/ | Number of Members 3/ |
Hypothetical Amount with Repurchase Expectations 4/ |
||
(In millions of SDRs) |
(In millions of SDRs) |
|||
Up to 100 percent of quota | 26,001 | 42 | 23,355 | |
100 to 200 percent of quota | 10,859 | 9 | 9,753 | |
200 to 300 percent of quota | 3,621 | 3 | 3,253 | |
Over 300 percent of quota | 1,770 | 1 | 1,590 | |
Total | 42,251 | 55 | 37,952 | |
1/ Excluding overdue credit. |
50. The amount that an individual member would pay under a level-based surcharge would depend on its particular circumstances, but would, in general, not be very large. A member with an arrangement of 125 percent of quota might pay very little or nothing under any of the three surcharge options, even if no advance repurchases were made (Table 7). A member with an arrangement of 250 percent of quota might pay surcharges equivalent to about 10 percent of regular charges (if graduation began at 100 percent of quota) if no advance repurchases were made. Under the option involving the highest starting point for surcharges, only members with outstanding credit above 300 percent of quota would pay surcharges (not shown in Table 7). Of course, should members advance repurchases or forego purchases to avoid the surcharge, no surcharge payments would be made (also not shown in Table 7). |
III. The Contingent Credit Lines51. The Board had a preliminary discussion in March, and a more detailed discussion in July, of possible changes to the CCL that could make this as yet unused facility more useful to members, and thus would better encourage their efforts at crisis prevention. The present chapter follows up on these discussions, with the intention of laying the groundwork for completion of the review of the CCL (now scheduled for end-September 2000) and for the implementation of a number of experimental changes, which might help establish, over the coming months, whether the CCL can become a useful instrument. A. The Activation Review52. There was broad agreement, in the July Board discussion, that the scope for judgments by the Fund in the CCL activation review should be reduced. In the activation review, the Board currently verifies that “(i) the member is experiencing exceptional balance of payments difficulties due to a large short-term financing need resulting from a sudden and disruptive loss of market confidence reflected in pressure on the capital account and the member’s reserves, (ii) these difficulties are judged to be largely beyond the member’s control and to be primarily from adverse developments in international capital markets consequent upon developments in one or several other countries, (iii) up to the time of the crisis, the member has successfully implemented the economic program that it had presented to the Board as a basis for its access to CCL resources, and (iv) the member is committed to adjusting policies to deal with any real economic impact that may follow from contagion.”40 |
Table 6. Level-Based Surcharge: Illustrative Impact on the Fund’s Annual Net Income 1/ | |||
---|---|---|---|
Zero Elasticity of Repurchases with Respect to Surcharges |
Infinite Elasticity of Repurchases with Respect to Surcharges |
||
(In millions of SDRs) | |||
Option L1 2/ | 180 | -132 | |
Option L2 2/ | 83 | -64 | |
Option L3 2/ | 18 | -41 | |
1/ Based on hypothetical amount of Fund credit outstanding at end-June 2000 (see Table 5), and assuming repurchase expectations and level-based surcharges had always been in effect. Includes hypothetical income loss of SDR 30 million due to lower outstanding credit resulting from early repurchase expectations. |
Illustrative Maximum Surcharge Paid Over Course of a Single Arrangement 1/ | |||||
By a Member Not Repurchasing Early |
By a Member Meeting Repurchase Expectations 2/ |
||||
Member with access of 125 percent of quota |
Member with access of 250 percent of quota |
Member with access of 125 percent of quota |
Member with access of 250 percent of quota |
||
(In percent) | |||||
Option L1 3/ | |||||
Stand-by | |||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 2.1 | 10.8 | 1.2 | 7.3 | |
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.12 | 0.59 | 0.07 | 0.40 | |
EFF | |||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 1.6 | 9.6 | 1.3 | 7.8 | |
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.09 | 0.53 | 0.07 | 0.43 | |
Option L2 3/ | |||||
Stand-by | |||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 0.0 | 4.2 | 0.0 | 2.4 | |
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.00 | 0.23 | 0.00 | 0.13 | |
EFF | |||||
As percent of charges 4/ | 0.0 | 3.2 | 0.0 | 2.7 | |
As average annual rate of charge 5/ | 0.00 | 0.18 | 0.00 | 0.15 | |
Option L3 3/ | No surcharges due | No surcharges due | |||
1/ See Box 3 for presentation of the assumed arrangement terms (apart from access levels). Elasticity of repurchases with respect to surcharges assumed to be zero. |
53. Three separate issues may be distinguished here—the Fund’s discretion to require policy changes, the scope for judgments by the Fund on the circumstances the member faces, and its judgment as to whether the member has adhered to its program. These relate respectively to condition (iv), conditions (i) and (ii), and condition (iii) above. The staff had proposed, in RoF II, reducing the Fund’s discretion to ask for policy changes in the activation review (condition (iv)). However, a number of Directors were also concerned about the extent to which the other conditions for the activation review reduce the degree of assurance given to the member and to markets regarding the availability of CCL resources. The remainder of this section will consider the three broad aspects of the CCL activation review in turn. (i) Policy changes 54. The staff had proposed, in RoF II, that the Fund’s discretion to require policy changes in the activation review be reduced. The Fund would verify conditions (i)-(iii) above in the review, but the member would be given the strong benefit of the doubt as to condition (iv). The “strong benefit of the doubt” here should be taken to mean that the Fund would proceed expeditiously, without comprehensively examining the member’s policy intentions, unless it had clear evidence that the member planned not to adjust policies to deal with any real economic impact from contagion. The amount available on completion of the activation review would be specified at the time of approval of the commitment under the CCL, and would—either as a rule or as a normal practice—be large (e.g., a set amount of 100 percent of quota, or a set fraction, perhaps a third, of the arrangement). 55. The activation review would thus fulfill two functions, and indeed in this construct two separate but possibly simultaneous reviews would be conducted (which are subsumed under the heading of the activation review in the present structure of the CCL): an “activation” review, and a “phasing” or “post-activation” review. The Fund would complete the activation review if it determines that conditions (i)-(iii) above are satisfied, and unless it had clear evidence that the member planned not to adjust policies to deal with any real economic impact of contagion; the prespecified amount would be made available at that time. However, for the purpose of specifying phasing and conditionality for the remainder of the amounts committed, the Fund and the member would have to reach understandings on the policies to be pursued from that point onward—understandings which would be sought in the “post-activation” review. The “activation” and “post-activation” reviews could be completed simultaneously, in which case the amount immediately released could be larger than that prespecified, on the grounds that the Fund and the member have already reached understandings on any policy adjustments that may be required. In most cases, however, it would seem likely that the activation review would be completed first, and expeditiously, and that it would be immediately followed by in-depth discussions between the member and the staff regarding the possible need for policy adjustments. 56. In the July discussion, there appeared to be close to a consensus on the staff proposal, with a few Directors suggesting more far-reaching changes. In particular, it was suggested that the activation review—or rather, in the terminology introduced above, the “post-activation” review—should focus exclusively on the stance of macroeconomic policies, since a temporary capital account shock would not be expected to signal a need for adjustments in structural policies. While it would indeed generally be expected that any “post-activation” policy changes would relate to macroeconomic policies, the staff would not recommend that the Fund irrevocably tie its hands in this regard, not least because it is conceivable that a crisis will reveal structural issues that had earlier gone unnoticed. (ii) The existence of a contagion-driven crisis 57. In the July Board discussion, a number of Directors expressed concern that the scope for judgments by the Fund as to whether a contagion-driven crisis was really underway could reduce the confidence of the member and of markets in the availability of resources. It was emphasized that the external circumstances in which the credit line might be drawn had been specified in the private contingent credit lines that at least one member had negotiated. 58. The staff believes that it is important to retain conditions (i) and (ii) for the activation review:
59. Alternatively, one could consider whether prespecified tests could be introduced, on which the judgment whether conditions (i) and (ii) were satisfied would be based. Such tests would specify “threshold conditions” which, if met, would constitute an assurance that conditions (i) and (ii) had been satisfied. In principle, such tests could be designed based on general principles, taking into account country-specific characteristics, and their specifics could be discussed between the authorities and the Fund, as part of the arrangement with CCL resources:
60. All in all, the staff sees only rather little scope to reduce the room for judgment by the Fund, in the activation review, as to whether a crisis is underway and whether it was triggered by external developments. At the same time, the degree of uncertainty introduced by this judgment may be relatively small. The experience of the last few years suggests that most observers agree when a crisis is underway, and even agree (given an assessment of domestic policies, see below) on whether external developments played a major part in its genesis. (iii) The member’s adherence to its program 61. It would also be difficult to eliminate the element of judgment in the final condition for the activation review, that the member should have adhered to its program. The member’s adherence to its program signals that it continues to meet the CCL eligibility criteria, which are complex and cannot be monitored simply by means of a limited number of conditions that could all be set out in the arrangement (along the lines of performance criteria).44 At the same time, and despite this complexity, the staff believes that the scope for judgment by the Fund on this score should not create excessive uncertainty. The member’s program is specified at the time of commitment of CCL resources, and reviewed at the time of the mid-term review, and there are thus clear benchmarks against which to measure performance in many areas. B. Exit62. At the July Board meeting, many Directors were concerned about how members might exit from the CCL, especially in a case where it becomes clear that the CCL eligibility criteria are no longer met. RoF II (paragraphs 88-89) discussed the difficulty of exiting for any reason—as markets may suspect there have been policy slippages even if there have not—and noted that this difficulty may represent an obstacle to members’ entering into the CCL. Directors seemed especially concerned, however, that the risk of triggering a crisis by making a member exit from the CCL in the event of a weakening of policies could make the Fund reluctant to enforce the CCL criteria as strictly as it should.45 63. Precautionary arrangements were mentioned as one possible route for exit in the event of a weakening of policies, which would reassure markets that policies remain reasonably sound. The staff believes that it would be useful to encourage a member that needs to exit from the CCL on this account to request an arrangement it would treat as precautionary (or indeed, if the need arose, one under which it would make purchases).46 On the other hand, it is not possible to compel a member to request an arrangement. 64. Many Directors were interested in a “graduated response” to policy slippages under an arrangement with CCL resources. It was suggested, for instance, that the amount that would be available upon completion of the activation review could be reduced in stages, and finally eliminated, in the event of a weakening of policies. 65. The notion of a graduated response, however, brings with it the idea of a “graduated CCL”—a CCL under which some members would be more highly “rated” than others. The graduated response would in itself require very finely-tuned judgments by the Fund, which would be even more difficult than the already difficult binary judgment that the Fund currently needs to make about CCL eligibility. Moreover, while it would be possible, in principle, to maintain a single standard for approval of a commitment of CCL resources and to introduce “graduation” only over the life of the commitment, the existence of different CCL “ratings” later in the commitment period would almost surely contaminate the signal the Fund seeks to give upon approval of access to the CCL. In addition, there is a substantial risk that any step in a graduated response—e.g., a reduction in the amount to be made available upon completion of the activation review—would have similar adverse effects on market perceptions as an outright exit. 66. The staff thus sees little scope for new procedures to resolve the issue of exit—although, at the same time, it would emphasize that exit from the CCL as currently designed is likely to take place in a way that in itself leads to a “graduated” reaction by markets. The reason for this is the same as in other arrangements. Inevitably, a typical Fund arrangement does not go off track suddenly, but gradually. It is not possible for the Fund to decide and declare that a member’s program has gone off track beyond hope of recovery; the possibility remains open that the program will come back on track, although the likelihood of this generally diminishes as time goes on. Thus, in practice, when a program goes off track a program review (or the approval of a new arrangement) becomes subject to increasing delays, until finally it may become clear that it will most probably not be completed. (And it is worth noting in this connection that delays in completing reviews under arrangements with emerging market economies—likely to be closely watched by markets—have rarely led to sudden or significant shifts in market sentiment.) Should a member that has been granted a commitment under the CCL no longer satisfy the eligibility criteria, similar mechanisms would come into play: non-completion of the mid-term review (or the absence of approval of a new arrangement with CCL resources, should the member have requested it) would probably be regarded by markets with increasing seriousness as time went on. C. The Rate of Charge67. There is considerable sympathy in the Board for the idea of reducing the rate of charge on the CCL, so as to better position the facility in relation to the SRF. The CCL rate of charge is currently identical to the SRF rate of charge—incorporating a surcharge of 300 basis points over the GRA rate of charge for one year from the date of the first purchase under the facility, rising by 50 basis points every six months up to a maximum of 500 basis points. 68. In the July Board discussion, Directors considered whether, as suggested in RoF II, the initial rate of charge on an arrangement with CCL resources should be aligned with the rate on a large stand-by arrangement entirely in the credit tranches.47 A number of Directors expressed a preference for a rate of charge above the rate on a regular stand-by arrangement. At the same time, other Directors considered that the rate should be the same as that on a regular stand-by arrangement. 69. Overall, unless the Board comes to a decision on charges quickly and finds a consensus on how the initial CCL rate of charge should relate to the rate on a regular stand-by arrangement, there may be a case for simply halving the starting surcharge on CCL resources. The initial surcharge would thus be 150 basis points—the lower end of the range discussed in RoF II. This surcharge would be only a little above the surcharge (120 basis points) that would be required to equalize the initial rate of charge on an arrangement with CCL resources and a stand-by arrangement in the credit tranches of 500 percent of quota (the upper end of the expected range of access under the CCL), if the Fund imposed a surcharge of 300 basis points on all use of Fund credit above the cumulative access limit. Reducing the starting surcharge to 150 basis points should be sufficient to introduce a significant difference in cost relative to the SRF. 70. At the same time, and as suggested in RoF II, the surcharge on CCL resources could rise on the same schedule as the surcharge under the SRF, in recognition of the likely short duration of the member’s difficulties. The surcharge would thus rise by 50 basis points one year after the first purchase under the facility, and by a further 50 basis points every six months thereafter. The ceiling on the surcharge could be reduced, relative to the ceiling in the SRF, to 350 basis points, maintaining the 150 basis point differential between SRF and CCL rates at all times. D. The Commitment Fee71. There is considerable support in the Board for the proposal to reduce the commitment fee applying to arrangements with CCL resources in order to encourage members to utilize the CCL. This is intended to address the concern that the commitment fee that applies to arrangements would apply, on approval, also to CCL resources, even though there is little prospect that these resources would be used. In order to address this concern while ensuring that the commitment fee applies uniformly to all arrangements (with or without CCL resources), as required by the Articles of Agreement, an effective reduction could be implemented through a change in Rule I-8 of the Fund’s Rules and Regulations.48 In particular, the basis for the payment of the commitment fee could be changed from “the total amount of the arrangement that could be purchased during each twelve-month period,” as currently provided, to “the total amount of scheduled purchases during each twelve-month period.” With this change, an arrangement with CCL resources would, on approval, trigger a commitment fee only on the purchases scheduled on approval (typically, only the first purchase of 5-25 percent of quota).49 No commitment fee would apply on the CCL resources until the activation review (or the post-activation review, as proposed), at which time the Executive Board would determine the schedule of availability of later purchases. However, there would be no effective commitment fee on the amount of the purchase upon activation since this portion of any commitment fee would be refunded. Portions of the commitment fee pertaining to subsequent scheduled purchases would be refunded only if and when those purchases were actually made.50 The necessary change in Rule I-8(a) could be made by a decision adopted by a 70 percent majority of the total voting power. |
IV. The Extended Fund Facility72. Directors generally agreed at the July Board meeting on RoF II that greater attention should be given to ensuring that arrangements under the EFF are granted only to cases fully consistent with the spirit and terms of the 1974 EFF Decision.These would be cases where a member’s balance of payments difficulties are expected to be relatively long term. Programs underpinning requests for EAs would be expected to continue to include appropriately strong structural reform programs, focused on achieving external viability in the longer-term as well as enhancing growth prospects. However, in contrast to some recent practice, the strength of the structural reform effort per se should not be considered sufficient reason for the use of EFF resources. In the absence of longer-term balance of payments difficulties, such structural programs could be implemented with the support of resources under a stand-by arrangement.51 Further, the need for a longer-term planning horizon, i.e., reforms that span a three-year period rather than the more typical one- to two-year period of the majority of stand-by arrangements, would also not be sufficient reason for granting resources under an EA. Such a planning horizon could be accommodated by a three-year SBA as well. 73. A priori, members that would be expected to be eligible for financing under the EFF would be primarily countries just above the threshold for PRGF eligibility, including PRGF graduates; PRGF-eligible countries (when EFF and PRGF resources are blended); and some early transition countries. EFF financing would continue to be available to other countries as well—including to countries opening their capital markets in a well-defined, structured process—as long as such members have reasonable grounds to expect their balance of payments difficulties to persist over the longer-term. The EFF would probably not be used by members with well-established access to captial markets, which are not likely to suffer from the problems described in the EFF Decision—severe payments imbalances, or slow growth and an inherently weak balance of payments—and whose balance of payments difficulties are likely to be of a relatively short-term nature. 74. The majority of Directors agreed that use of the EFF on a precautionary basis should be exceptional. Several Directors saw merit in precautionary EAs, because they provide confidence to members making difficult policy decisions, by giving assurance that resources will be available over a reasonably extended period if a balance of payments need should develop during a period of comprehensive economic adjustment. At the same time, it was recognized that the circumstances in which a member without an immediate need for Fund resources would develop longer-term balance of payments difficulties would be rare. It is not unlikely that a member without an immediate balance of payments problem may, in the course of implementing a medium-term structural adjustment program, develop a balance of payments need. This could be the result of adverse market developments not related specifically to the reform program or directly stemming from the program itself, for example, as a result of extensive resource reallocation or the relaxation of capital controls. However, there will rarely if ever be a high likelihood that this need would develop into a longer-term balance of payments problem justifying longer-term financing. The presumption is that if a member has appropriate policies and no need for Fund resources to begin with, its balance of payments position would likely recover within the repayment terms provided under a stand-by arrangement. Should this not be the case, the member could always request a follow-up arrangement under the EFF. |
V. Post-Program Monitoring75. The objective of stronger post-program monitoring (PPM) is to provide for closer monitoring of the circumstances and policies of members whose arrangement has expired but that continue to have Fund credit outstanding. Stronger PPM could provide an early warning of policies which could call into question a member’s continued progress toward external viability, and thus could eventually imperil Fund resources, or at the least indicate that such resources were not being used (in the sense of continuing to be used) for their intended purpose. 76. In RoF II, the staff proposed PPM procedures that would aim to provide additional safeguards to Fund resources. Under current practices, the staff monitors developments in members with outstanding Fund resources relatively intensively, but this does not usually formally involve the Executive Board. RoF II proposed procedures that entailed regular (say, semi-annual) staff discussions with a member, with a particular focus on macroeconomic and those structural policies that have a bearing on external viability, which would be reported to the Board in the form of a brief Board paper. These procedures would be grounded in the use of the existing consultation clauses in all arrangements. The staff suggested that this monitoring could be carried out for members with relatively high Fund credit outstanding and/or for members where the risk of encountering difficulties in repaying the Fund was seen as high. 77. During the July Board discussion, a number of Directors saw no need to formalize practices on PPM. In particular, they expressed a strong preference for PPM on a case-by-case basis rather than on the basis of the automatic application of formal criteria. 78. An alternative proposal—noted by the Chairman in his concluding remarks—would involve more formal procedures, but applied on a case-by-case basis. PPM could be based on the recommendation of the Managing Director, and the agreement of the Board, on the occasion of a member’s Article IV Consultation discussion or during informal country matters sessions.52 It would involve discussions with the member and the preparation by the staff of a Board paper focusing on recent developments and policies, and how they affect the member’s medium-term prospects and capacity to repay the Fund. The Board paper would recommend, and the Executive Board would decide, whether there should be further PPM. The Managing Director would be guided in his or her recommendations by developments in a member’s policies and external position that he or she would see as posing risks to the member’s progress toward external viability.53 79. At the same time, it is important to note that this proposal could represent only a minor strengthening relative to current practices. The ad hoc application of the procedure could well result in very infrequent implementation, just as, for instance, the existing ad hoc procedures for supplemental/special consultations (which are instruments of surveillance) have been used only twice since the relevant decision was adopted in 1979. The fear of adverse market reaction and concerns about uniformity of treatment could contribute to such an outcome. A rule, or alternatively a presumption, that members meeting certain criteria (e.g., a level of Fund credit outstanding above a certain threshold) would engage in PPM might help ensure a more frequent application, which in itself should alleviate the concern that members “singled out” for PPM might suffer an adverse market reaction. 80. Consistent with the Fund’s policy on transparency, the staff would recommend that, following a PPM discussion, publication of a Public Information Notice (PIN), based on a summing up of the Board discussion, be encouraged. While dissemination to the public of discussions on use of Fund resources54 is through a Chairman’s Statement, a PIN would be a more natural vehicle for a summary of a PPM discussion that might involve substantial concerns about the course of a member’s policies. As with other PINs, the member’s consent would be required for publication. The use of PINs following a discussion about use of Fund resources would require a change in the Decision governing PINs. 81. The Board might wish to review the implementation of, and procedures for, PPM in about 18 months. |
VI. Issues for Discussion82. Directors may wish to indicate whether they believe that there is a problem, or a significant risk, of excessive use of Fund resources, and, if so, whether they believe this problem to be concentrated in the area of prolonged use, long use following the resolution of a balance of payments problem, or large use (including long use of large amounts of Fund resources). 83. Directors may wish to comment on the following approaches to address potential issues relating to unduly long or large use of Fund resources: (i) with a view to addressing long use of Fund resources:
(ii) with a view to addressing large use of Fund resources (including long use of large amounts): graduating the rate of charge with the amount of resources outstanding, and whether the options presented in Figure 2 (or others) would be desirable or acceptable. 84. Directors may wish to comment on whether the following changes should be introduced into the Contingent Credit Lines (CCL):
Directors may also wish to comment on whether they see possibilities further to reduce the scope for judgment by the Fund in other areas of the activation review, and whether they see scope for new procedures that would make it easier for a member to exit from the CCL in case of policy slippages. 85. On the EFF, Directors may wish to confirm the sense of the Board in the July discussion—that access to the EFF should be granted only in cases where a member’s balance of payments difficulties are expected to be relatively long-term, and that use of the EFF on a precautionary basis would be expected to be exceptional. 86. Directors may wish to comment on possible procedures for stronger post-program monitoring—in particular:
87. The introduction of some of these policies would require Board decisions. The voting majorities required for these decisions are set forth in Table 8. |
Changes | Required Majority 1/ | |
1. Introducing a schedule of early repurchase expectations. | ||
That does not allow the conversion of expectations into obligations | Majority of votes cast | |
That allows the conversion of expectations into obligations | 85 | |
2. Graduation of the rate of charge | ||
Graduation with time starting from each purchase | 70 | |
Graduation with time starting from the first purchase under an arrangement | 70-85 2/ | |
Graduation with amount of credit outstanding | 70 | |
3. CCL | ||
Changes to the conditions for the activation and post-activation reviews | Majority of votes cast | |
Reducing the rate of surcharge | 70 | |
Changing the basis on which commitment fees are charged (Rule I-8(a)) | 70 | |
1/ In percent of total voting power, unless otherwise specified. |
ANNEX
Prepayment Clauses in Other Creditors’ OperationsIn this paper, prepayment clauses in creditors’ financing operations are understood as clauses in official or commercial credit agreements with sovereign borrowers whereby mandatory repayments ahead of an agreed repayment schedule are linked to early repayments to other creditors, including to the Fund. These clauses are potentially relevant when designing or implementing policies targeting early repayments to the Fund, because of their possible negative financial consequences for member countries making repayments. Prepayment clauses are common in commercial syndicated loans and Brady bonds,55 but not widespread—if present at all—in other types of bonds, and particularly in the growing Eurobond market. Given that the composition of private capital flows to emerging markets has shifted away from syndicated loans in recent years, prepayment clauses to commercial creditors have become progressively less important in the 1990s, though they could become more relevant should syndicated lending again grow in importance in the future. Implicit or explicit prepayment clauses are present in official creditors’ concerted lending operations, but usually not in their individual operations. The Fund has tried to minimize the financial consequences to members of early repayments to itself by discouraging members from signing clauses in commercial credit agreements that link prepayments to early repurchase to the Fund, or by encouraging them to seek modifications of these clauses in anticipation of the possibility of an early repurchase to the Fund.56 The Fund’s arguments in this respect are strengthened by the fact that early repurchases are not at the member’s discretion, but rather part of the repurchase structure of the Fund. By contrast, this approach would not help to contain the indirect financial costs to individual members of an entirely incentive-driven policy to address long use, since incentives would result in advance repurchases that would be clearly voluntary, and thus could not help but trigger prepayment clauses. |
1See “Review of Fund Facilities—Preliminary Considerations,” EBS/00/37, March 2, 2000 (hereafter RoF I) and “Summing Up by the Acting Chairman – Review of Fund Facilities—Preliminary Considerations, EBM/00/27,” BUFF/00/41, March 24, 2000 (hereafter Summing Up – RoF I); and “Review of Fund Facilities—Further Considerations,” EBS/00/131, July 10, 2000 (including Supplement 1, “Supplementary Information on Rates of Charge”) (hereafter RoF II) and “Concluding Remarks by the Chairman – Review of Fund Facilities—Further Considerations, EBM/00/74,” BUFF/00/123, Revision 1, August 7, 2000 (hereafter Concluding Remarks - RoF II). |