Classification of Exchange Rate Arrangements and Monetary Policy Frameworks Home Page





De Facto Classification of Exchange Rate Regimes and Monetary Policy Framework

Data as of July 31, 2006

1. This classification system is based on members' actual, de facto, arrangements as identified by IMF staff, which may differ from their officially announced arrangements. The scheme ranks exchange rate arrangements on the basis of their degree of flexibility and the existence of formal or informal commitments to exchange rate paths. It distinguishes among different forms of exchange rate regimes, in addition to arrangements with no separate legal tender, to help assess the implications of the choice of exchange rate arrangement for the degree of monetary policy independence. The system presents members' exchange rate regimes and monetary policy frameworks to provide greater transparency in the classification scheme and to illustrate the relationship between exchange rate regimes and different monetary policy frameworks. The following explains the categories.

Exchange rate regimes

Exchange arrangements with no separate legal tender

2. The currency of another country circulates as the sole legal tender (formal dollarization), or the member belongs to a monetary or currency union in which the same legal tender is shared by the members of the union. Adopting such regimes implies the complete surrender of the monetary authorities' control over domestic monetary policy.

Currency board arrangements

3. A monetary regime based on an explicit legislative commitment to exchange domestic currency for a specified foreign currency at a fixed exchange rate, combined with restrictions on the issuing authority to ensure the fulfillment of its legal obligation. This implies that domestic currency will be issued only against foreign exchange and that it remains fully backed by foreign assets, leaving little scope for discretionary monetary policy and eliminating traditional central bank functions, such as monetary control and lender-of-last-resort. Some flexibility may still be afforded, depending on how strict the banking rules of the currency board arrangement are.

Conventional fixed peg arrangements

4. The country pegs its currency within margins of ±1 percent or less vis-à-vis another currency; a cooperative arrangement, such as the ERM II; or a basket of currencies, where the basket is formed from the currencies of major trading or financial partners and weights reflect the geographical distribution of trade, services, or capital flows. The currency composites can also be standardized, as in the case of the SDR. There is no commitment to keep the parity irrevocably. The exchange rate may fluctuate within narrow margins of less than ±1 percent around a central rate—or the maximum and minimum value of the exchange rate may remain within a narrow margin of 2 percent—for at least three months. The monetary authority maintains the fixed parity through direct intervention (i.e., via sale/purchase of foreign exchange in the market) or indirect intervention (e.g., via the use of interest rate policy, imposition of foreign exchange regulations, exercise of moral suasion that constrains foreign exchange activity, or through intervention by other public institutions). Flexibility of monetary policy, though limited, is greater than in the case of exchange arrangements with no separate legal tender and currency boards because traditional central banking functions are still possible, and the monetary authority can adjust the level of the exchange rate, although relatively infrequently.

Pegged exchange rates within horizontal bands

5. The value of the currency is maintained within certain margins of fluctuation of more than ±1 percent around a fixed central rate or the margin between the maximum and minimum value of the exchange rate exceeds 2 percent. As in the case of conventional fixed pegs, reference may be made to a single currency, a cooperative arrangement, or a currency composite. There is a limited degree of monetary policy discretion, depending on the band width.

Crawling pegs

6. The currency is adjusted periodically in small amounts at a fixed rate or in response to changes in selective quantitative indicators, such as past inflation differentials vis-à-vis major trading partners, differentials between the inflation target and expected inflation in major trading partners. The rate of crawl can be set to adjust for measured inflation or other indicators (backward looking), or set at a preannounced fixed rate and/or below the projected inflation differentials (forward looking). Maintaining a crawling peg imposes constraints on monetary policy in a manner similar to a fixed peg system.

Exchange rates within crawling bands

7. The currency is maintained within certain fluctuation margins of at least ±1 percent around a central rate—or the margin between the maximum and minimum value of the exchange rate exceeds 2 percent—and the central rate or margins are adjusted periodically at a fixed rate or in response to changes in selective quantitative indicators. The degree of exchange rate flexibility is a function of the band width. Bands are either symmetric around a crawling central parity or widen gradually with an asymmetric choice of the crawl of upper and lower bands (in the latter case, there may be no preannounced central rate). The commitment to maintain the exchange rate within the band imposes constraints on monetary policy, with the degree of policy independence being a function of the band width.

Managed floating with no predetermined path for the exchange rate

8. The monetary authority attempts to influence the exchange rate without having a specific exchange rate path or target. Indicators for managing the rate are broadly judgmental (e.g., balance of payments position, international reserves, parallel market developments), and adjustments may not be automatic. Intervention may be direct or indirect.

Independently floating

9. The exchange rate is market-determined, with any official foreign exchange market intervention aimed at moderating the rate of change and preventing undue fluctuations in the exchange rate, rather than at establishing a level for it.

Monetary policy framework

Exchange rate anchor

10. The monetary authority stands ready to buy or sell foreign exchange at given quoted rates to maintain the exchange rate at its preannounced level or range; the exchange rate serves as the nominal anchor or intermediate target of monetary policy. This type of regime covers exchange rate regimes with no separate legal tender; currency board arrangements; fixed pegs with and without bands; and crawling pegs with and without bands.

Monetary aggregate anchor

11. The monetary authority uses its instruments to achieve a target growth rate for a monetary aggregate, such as reserve money, M1, or M2, and the targeted aggregate becomes the nominal anchor or intermediate target of monetary policy.

Inflation targeting framework

12. This involves the public announcement of medium-term numerical targets for inflation with an institutional commitment by the monetary authority to achieve these targets. Additional key features include increased communication with the public and the markets about the plans and objectives of monetary policymakers and increased accountability of the central bank for attaining its inflation objectives. Monetary policy decisions are guided by the deviation of forecasts of future inflation from the announced target, with the inflation forecast acting (implicitly or explicitly) as the intermediate target of monetary policy.

Fund-supported or other monetary program

13. This involves implementation of monetary and exchange rate policies within the confines of a framework that establishes floors for international reserves and ceilings for net domestic assets of the central bank. Indicative targets for reserve money may be appended to this system. Countries that maintain nominal anchors, exchange rate anchors, monetary anchors, or inflation targeting frameworks are classifies under those respective rubrics.

Other

The country has no explicitly stated nominal anchor but rather monitors various indicators in conducting monetary policy, or there is no relevant information available for the country.



De Facto Exchange Rate Arrangements and Anchors of Monetary Policy
as of July 31, 2006 1/

Exchange Rate Regime

(Number of countries)

Monetary Policy Framework

Exchange rate anchor

Monetary aggregate target

Inflation targeting framework

IMF-supported or other monetary program

Other2

Exchange arrangements with no separate legal tender (41)

Another currency as legal tender         (9)        

ECCU (6)3

CFA franc zone (14)

     

Euro area (12)
Austria
Belgium
Finland
France
Germany
Greece
Ireland
Italy
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Portugal
Spain

WAEMU

CAEMC

Ecuador
El Salvador4
Kiribati
Marshall Islands
Micronesia, Fed. States of
Palau
Panama
San Marino
Timor-Leste, Dem. Rep. of

Antigua and Barbuda
Dominica*
Grenada*
St. Kitts and Nevis
St. Lucia
St. Vincent and the Grenadines

Benin*
Burkina Faso*
Côte d'Ivoire
Guinea-Bissau
Mali*
Niger*
Senegal
Togo

Cameroon*
Central African Rep.
Chad*
Congo, Rep. of*
Equatorial Guinea
Gabon

Currency board arrangements (7)

Bosnia and Herzegovina
Brunei Darussalam
Bulgaria*
Hong Kong SAR
Djibouti
Estonia5
Lithuania5

       

Other conventional fixed peg arrangements (52)

Against a single currency (47)

China†6
Guyana*7, 8
Sierra Leone*7
Suriname7, 8, 9

   

Pakistan†7

Aruba
Bahamas, The9
Bahrain, Kingdom of
Barbados
Belarus7
Belize
Bhutan
Bolivia7, 10
Cape Verde
China†6
Comoros11
Egypt7
Eritrea
Ethiopia7
Guyana*7, 8
Honduras*†7
Iraq*7
Jordan7
Kuwait
Latvia5
Lebanon7
Lesotho
Macedonia, FYR*7
Maldives

Malta5
Mauritania7
Namibia
Nepal*
Netherlands Antilles
Oman
Pakistan†7
Qatar
Rwanda*
Saudi Arabia
Seychelles7
Sierra Leone*7
Solomon Islands7
Suriname7, 9
Swaziland
Syrian Arab Rep.9
Trinidad and Tobago7
Turkmenistan7
Ukraine7
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela, Rep. Bolivariana de
Vietnam7
Zimbabwe9

 

Against a composite (5)

       
 

Fiji
Libyan Arab Jamahiriya
Morocco

Samoa
Vanuatu

       

Pegged exchange rates within horizontal
bands (6)12

Within a cooperative arrangement (4)
Cyprus5
Denmark5
Slovak Rep.†5
Slovenia5

Other band arrangements (2)
Hungary†
Tonga

 

Hungary†
Slovak Rep.†5

   

Crawling pegs (5)

Azerbaijan7
Botswana9
Costa Rica
Iran, I.R. of7, 13
Nicaragua*

Iran, I.R. of7, 13

     

Managed floating with no pre-determined path for the exchange rate (51)

 

Argentina
Bangladesh*
Cambodia
Gambia, The7
Ghana*7
Haiti7
Jamaica7
Lao P.D.R.9
Madagascar*7
Malawi*
Mauritius
Moldova*
Mongolia
Sri Lanka7
Sudan
Tajikistan
Tunisia
Uruguay*
Yemen, Rep. of7
Zambia*

Colombia*
Czech Rep.
Guatemala7
Peru*
Romania
Serbia, Rep. of14
Thailand

Afghanistan, I.R. of*
Armenia*7
Georgia*
Kenya*
Kyrgyz Rep.*
Mozambique*7

Algeria
Angola
Burundi*
Croatia*
Dominican Rep.* 
Guinea7
India
Kazakhstan
Liberia7
Malaysia
Myanmar
Nigeria7
Papua New Guinea7
Paraguay*
Russian Federation
São Tomé and Príncipe*
Singapore
Uzbekistan9

Independently floating (25)

 

Albania*
Congo, Dem. Rep. of
Indonesia
Uganda

Australia
Brazil
Canada
Chile
Iceland
Israel
Korea
Mexico
New Zealand
Norway
Philippines
Poland
South Africa
Sweden
Turkey*
United Kingdom

Tanzania*7

Japan
Somalia9, 15
Switzerland
United States

Sources: IMF staff reports; IMF Recent Economic Developments; and IMF staff estimates.
1 An asterisk (*) indicates that the country has an IMF-supported or other monetary program. A dagger (†) indicates that the country adopts more than one nominal anchor in conducting monetary policy (it should be noted, however, that it would not be possible, for practical reasons, to include in this table which nominal anchor plays the principal role in conducting monetary policy).
2 Includes countries that have no explicitly stated nominal anchor, but rather monitor various indicators in conducting monetary policy.
3 The ECCU has a currency board arrangement.
4 The printing of new colones, the domestic currency, is prohibited, but the existing stock of colones will continue to circulate along with the U.S. dollar as legal tender until all colón notes wear out physically.
5 The member participates in the ERM II.
6 On July 21, 2005, China announced a 2.1% revaluation of the renminbi-U.S. dollar exchange rate and a change in its exchange rate arrangement to allow the value of the renminbi to fluctuate based on market supply and demand with reference to an undisclosed basket of currencies. To permit a greater role for market forces in determining the renminbi exchange rate, steps have been taken since July 2005 to liberalize and develop China's foreign exchange markets, including the establishment of an over-the-counter spot foreign exchange market and markets for currency swaps and futures. From end-July 2005 to end-July 2006, the renminbi exchange rate was more flexible, but the fluctuation in the renminbi-U.S dollar exchange rate was less than the 2% range (for a three-month period) used in the IMF's de facto exchange rate classification system as an indicator for a conventional fixed peg exchange rate arrangement.
7 The regime operating de facto in the country is different from its de jure regime.
8 There is no evidence of direct intervention by the authorities in the foreign exchange market.
9 The member maintains an exchange arrangement involving more than one foreign exchange market. The arrangement shown is that maintained in the major market.
10 This is a de facto classification resulting from the methodology described in Appendix II of this document. The Bolivian authorities consider their regime as a crawling peg and have not committed to the current level of the exchange rate.
11 Comoros has the same arrangement with the French Treasury as the CFA franc zone countries.
12 The bands for these countries are as follows: Cyprus ±15%, Denmark ±2.25%, Hungary ±15%, Slovak Republic ±15%, Slovenia (undisclosed), and Tonga ±5%.
13 The rial crawls vis-à-vis an unannounced basket of currencies.
14 While the current monetary framework is anchored by the announcement of core inflation objectives, the National Bank of Serbia is preparing the transition to full-fledged inflation targeting.
15 Insufficient information on the country is available to confirm this classification, and so the classification of the last official consultation is used.