Executive Summary
Against the background of highly volatile international capital flows
and the associated financial instability experienced by a number of major
emerging market economies in recent years, the role of the IMF in capital
account liberalization has been a topic of major controversy. The IMF's
role is particularly controversial because capital account liberalization
is an area where there is little professional consensus. Moreover, although current
account liberalization is among the IMF's official purposes outlined
in its Articles of Agreement, the IMF has no explicit mandate to promote capital
account liberalization. Indeed, the Articles give the IMF only limited
jurisdiction over issues related to the capital account. Nevertheless,
the IMF has given greater attention to capital account issues in recent
decades, in light of the increasing importance of international capital
flows for member countries' macroeconomic management. In view of these
facts, an independent assessment of how the IMF has addressed capital
account issues seems warranted.
The evaluation seeks
to (1) contribute to transparency by documenting
what in practice has been the IMF's approach to capital account liberalization
and related issues; and (2) identify areas, if any, where the IMF's
instruments and operating methods might be improved, in order to deal
with capital account issues more effectively. The issues addressed in
the evaluation cover not only capital account liberalization but also
capital flow management issues, including particularly the temporary
use of capital controls. The evaluation, however, does not address the
question of whether liberal capital accounts are intrinsically beneficialon
which the broader academic literature has not been able to provide a
definitive answeror whether the Articles of Agreement should be amended
to give the IMF an explicit mandate and jurisdiction on capital account
issues. Many aspects of these issues are not amenable to evidence from
the evaluation. However, the evaluation does shed some light on the consequence
of the lack of explicit mandate and jurisdiction on the IMF's work on
capital account issues.
The report begins
by reviewing the IMF's general operational approach and analysis as
they evolved from the early 1990s into the early 2000s.
It then assesses the IMF's country work in terms of (1) its role
in capital account liberalization during 1990-2002, (2) its policy
advice to member countries on managing capital flows during the same
period, and (3) its ongoing work on capital account issues (where
outstanding issues are identified for 2003-04). The report concludes
by offering two broad recommendations.
A. The IMF's General Operational Approach and Analysis
Despite the ambiguity left by the Articles of Agreement about its role
in capital account issues, the IMF responded to the changing international
environment by paying increasing attention to issues related to the capital
account. Concurrent with the initiatives to amend the Articles to give
the IMF an explicit mandate for capital account liberalization and jurisdiction
over members' capital account policies, the IMF expanded the scope of
its operational work in the area. It encouraged the staff to give greater
emphasis to capital account issues in Article IV consultations and technical
assistance and to promote capital account liberalization more actively.
In multilateral surveillance,
the IMF's analysis prior to the mid-1990s tended to emphasize the benefits
to developing countries of greater access
to international capital flows and to pay comparatively less attention
to the potential risks of capital flow volatility. More recently, however,
the IMF has paid greater attention to various risk factors, including
the linkage between industrial country policies and international capital
flows as well as the more fundamental causes and implications of their
boom-and-bust cycles. Still, the focus of the analysis remains on what
emerging market countries should do to cope with the volatility of capital flows
(for example, in the areas of macroeconomic and exchange rate policy,
strengthened financial sectors, and greater transparency). Although the
IMF has addressed the moral hazard aspect of boom-and-bust cycles by
encouraging greater exchange rate flexibility in recipient countries
and attempting to limit access to IMF resources during a crisis, it has
not been at the forefront of the debate on what, if anything, can be
done to reduce the cyclicality of capital movements through regulatory
measures targeted at institutional investors in the source countries.
From the beginning of the 1990s, the IMF's management, staff, and Executive
Board were aware of the potential risks of premature capital account
liberalization and there is no evidence to suggest that they promoted
capital account liberalization indiscriminately. They also acknowledged
the need for a sound financial system in order to minimize the risks
of liberalization. Such awareness, however, largely remained at the conceptual
level and did not lead to operational advice on preconditions, pace,
and sequencing until later in the 1990s. At the same time, a subtle change
was taking place within the institution. As preliminary evidence emerged
on the apparent effectiveness of Chile's capital controls in the mid-1990s,
some in the IMF began to take a favorable view of the use of capital
controls as a temporary measure to deal with large capital inflows.
In the event, the
proposed amendment of the Articles put forward in the late 1990s failed
to garner sufficient support, leaving ambiguity
about the role of the IMF. In the meantime, something of a consensusthe
so-called "integrated" approachhas emerged within the IMF
that places capital account liberalization as part of a comprehensive
program of economic reforms in the macroeconomic policy framework, the
domestic financial system, and prudential regulations. While few would
disagree with the prudence and judiciousness of the new approach, it
has proved to be difficult to apply as an operational guide to sequencing
because it emphasizes all of the potential interlinkages but does not
provide clear criteria for identifying a hierarchy of risks. Moreover,
these views remain unofficial, as they have not been explicitly endorsed
by the Executive Board.
B. The IMF's Country Work
The evaluation assesses
the IMF's country work in terms of the following criteria: (1) Was there any difference between the IMF's general
policy pronouncements and the advice it gave to individual countries?
(2) Was the IMF's policy advice operational and based on solid evidence?
(3) How did the IMF's advice change over time, and did this change
keep pace with available evidence? (4) Did the IMF give similar advice
to countries in similar situations? and (5) Was the policy advice
on the capital account set in a broader assessment of the authorities'
macroeconomic policies and institutional framework?
Capital account liberalization
During the 1990s, the IMF clearly encouraged capital account liberalization,
but the evaluation suggests that, in all the countries that liberalized
the capital account, partially or almost fully, the process was for the
most part driven by the country authorities' own economic and political
agendas. In none of the program cases examined did the IMF require capital
account liberalization as formal conditionality (which is understood
to mean prior actions, performance criteria, or structural benchmarks),
although aspects of it were often included in the authorities' overall
policy package presented to the IMF. This is consistent with the interpretation
of the Articles of Agreement, which states that the IMF, as a condition
for the use of its resources, cannot require a member to remove controls
on capital movements. In the first half of the 1990s, in encouraging
capital account liberalization, the IMF seldom raised the issue of pace
and sequencing. The staff occasionally expressed concern over financial
sector weakness or macroeconomic instability, but this did not translate
into concrete operational advice. From around 1994, and more noticeably
following the East Asian crisis, the IMF began increasingly to give emphasis
to the need to satisfy certain preconditions; in general, the IMF's approach
in its country work was quite pragmatic, especially in this later period,
and often accepted the authorities' own views on the appropriate pace
and sequencing of liberalization.
Managing capital inflows
As countries experienced large capital inflows and associated macroeconomic
challenges in the 1990s, the issue of how to manage large capital inflows
became a routine subject of discussion between the IMF and the country
authorities. The staff's policy advice was largely in line with the policy
conclusions typically derived from the scholarly literature on open economy
macroeconomics. To deal with large capital inflows, it advocated tightening
fiscal policy and greater exchange rate flexibility. The staff's position
on sterilization emphasized its quasi-fiscal costs and longer-term ineffectiveness
but was, to a remarkable extent, supportive of the country authorities'
policy choices, whatever they may have been. In a few instances, the
staff also recommended further trade liberalization, liberalization of
capital outflows, and tightening of prudential regulation as measures
to deal with large capital inflows. These and other structural measures,
however, received relatively little attention in the IMF's policy advice,
although in recent years increasing attention has been given to strengthening
the financial sector regulatory framework, primarily in the context of
the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP). Given the IMF's focus and comparative
advantage, this was probably appropriate.
Temporary use of capital controls
Use of capital controls has been a controversial subject, not only within
the IMF but also in the academic and official policymaking communities.
It is possible here to make a broad characterization that the IMF staff
was in principle opposed to the use of such instruments, either on inflows
or outflows. Its view was that they were not very effective, especially
in the long run, and could not be a substitute for the required adjustments
in macroeconomic and exchange rate policies. Even so, from the earliest
days, the IMF staff displayed a remarkable degree of sympathy with some
countries in the use of capital controls. In a few cases, both before
and after the crises of 1997-98, it even suggested that market-based
controls could be introduced as a prudential measure. As a general rule,
the IMF staff, in line with the evolution of the institution's view,
became much more accommodating of the use of capital controls over time,
albeit as a temporary, second-best instrument.
Ongoing country dialogue on capital account issues
In ongoing country work, as documented for the period of 2003-04, IMF
staff has been quite accommodating of the authorities' policy choices
when they have involved a gradual approach to capital account liberalization
or temporary use of controls. In terms of capital account liberalization,
the staff has sometimes been more cautious than the authorities (as in
Russia in 2003) when their preferred policy has been to liberalize the
capital account quickly. In most cases, the staff has taken a medium-term
perspective and has emphasized the importance of meeting certain preconditions,
the most important of which are fiscal consolidation, a sound financial
system, and the adoption of a floating exchange rate (usually with inflation
targeting).
In terms of advice on temporary use of capital controls, IMF staff seldom
challenged the authorities' decision and has even supported market-based
controls in some cases. There was a slight difference in emphasis across
countries. In a few countries (as in Russia in 2004), the staff expressed
forcefully the view that capital controls, no matter how useful they
might be in the short run, could not be expected to be effective over
time and should not be used as a substitute for appropriate adjustment
in macroeconomic policies. In others (as in Colombia), the use of controls
introduced by the authorities did not figure prominently in policy discussions.
In still other cases (as in Croatia), the staff recommended a market-based
control, albeit as a last resort measure.
C. Overall Assessment
Throughout the 1990s, the IMF undoubtedly encouraged countries that wanted to move ahead with capital account liberalization, and even acted as a cheerleader when it wished to do so, especially before the East
Asian crisis. However, there is no evidence to suggest that it exerted
significant leverage to push countries to move faster than they were
willing to go. The process of liberalization was often driven by the
authorities' own economic and political agendas, including accession to the Organization for Economic Cooperation an Development (OECD) or the European Union (EU) and commitments under bilateral or regional trade agreements.
In encouraging capital account liberalization, the IMF pointed out the
risks inherent in an open capital account as well as the need for a sound
financial system, even from the beginning. The problem was that these
risks were insufficiently highlighted, and the recognition of the risks
and preconditions did not translate into operational advice on pace and
sequencing until later in the 1990s (and even thereafter the policy advice
has often been of limited practical applicability).
In multilateral surveillance, the IMF's analysis emphasized the benefits
to developing countries of greater access to international capital flows,
while paying comparatively less attention to the risks inherent in their
volatility. As a consequence, its policy advice was directed more toward
emerging market recipients of capital flows, and focused on how to manage
large capital inflows and boom-and-bust cycles; little policy advice
was offered, in the context of multilateral surveillance, on how source
countries might help to reduce the volatility of capital flows on the
supply side. In more recent years, the IMF's analysis of such supply-side
factors has intensified. Even so, the focus of policy advicebeyond the
analysis of macroeconomic policies covering large current account imbalancesremains
on the recipient countries.
In country work there was apparent inconsistency in the IMF's advice
on capital account issues. Sequencing was mentioned in some countries
but not in others; advice on managing capital inflows was in line with
standard policy prescriptions, but the intensity differed across countries
or across time (with no clear rationale provided for the difference);
and a range of views was expressed on use of capital controls (though
greater convergence toward accommodation was observed over time). Policy
advice must of necessity be tailored to country-specific circumstances,
so uniformity cannot be the only criterion for judging the quality of
the IMF's advice. Country documents, however, provide only an insufficient
analytical basis for making a definitive judgment on how the staff's
policy advice was linked to its assessment of the macroeconomic and institutional
environments in which it was given. While one can explain why certain
types of advice were offered in some individual cases, no generalization
is possible about the consistency of the IMF's overall policy advice.
Even so, it appears that the apparent inconsistency to a large extent
reflected reliance on the discretion of individual IMF staff members,
and not necessarily the consistent application of the same principles
to different circumstances.
The evaluation suggests that the IMF has learned over time on capital
account issues. This seems to have affected the work of the IMF through
two channels. First, the IMF's general approach did respondalbeit graduallyto
new developments or new evidence. Second, independent of how the general
approach changed, some of the learning became more quickly reflected
in the IMF's country work through its impact on individual staff members.
The lack of a formal IMF position on capital account liberalization and
the associated partial disconnect between general operational guidelines
and country work had different consequences. On the one hand, this gave
individual staff members freedom to use their own professional and intellectual
judgment in dealing with specific country issues. On the other hand,
the disconnect reflected the inherent ambiguity of this aspect of the
IMF's work and led to some lack of consistency in country work, as noted
above.
In more recent years, somewhat greater consistency and clarity has been
brought to bear on the IMF's approach to capital account issues. For
the most part, the new paradigm upholds the role of country ownership
in determining pace and sequencing; takes a more consistently cautious
and nuanced approach to encouraging capital account convertibility; and
acknowledges the usefulness of capital controls under certain conditions,
particularly controls on inflows. But these are still unofficial views,
no matter how widely they may be shared within the institution. While
the majority of staff members now appear to accept this new paradigm,
some continue to feel uneasiness with the lack of a clear position by
the institution.
D. Recommendations
The evaluation suggests two main areas in which the IMF can improve
its work on capital account issues.
Recommendation 1: There is a need for more clarity on the IMF's approach
to capital account issues. The evaluation is not focused on the
arguments for and against amending the Articles of Agreement, but it
does suggest that the ambiguity about the role of the IMF with regard
to capital account issues has led to some lack of consistency in the
work of the IMF across countries. This may reflect the lack of clarity
in the Articles, but with or without a change in the Articles it should
be possible to improve the consistency of the IMF's country work in
other ways. For example:
- The place of capital account issues in IMF surveillance could
be clarified. It is generally understood that while under current
arrangements the IMF has neither explicit mandate nor jurisdiction
on capital account issues, it has a responsibility to exercise surveillance
over certain aspects of members' capital account policies. However,
much ambiguity remains on the scope of IMF surveillance in this area.
The clearest statement of the basis for surveillance of capital account
issues is embodied in the 1977 Executive Board decision calling for
surveillance to consider certain capital account restrictions introduced
for balance of payments purposes, but the qualification limiting the
scope to balance of payments reasons is too restrictive to cover the
range of capital account issues that surface in the IMF's country work.
On the other hand, the broader statement of the IMF's surveillance
responsibility, found in the preamble to Article IV, is too wide to
serve as an operational guide to surveillance on capital account issues.
There would be value if the Executive Board were formally to clarify
the scope of IMF surveillance on capital account issues. Such a clarification
would recognize that capital account policy is intimately connected
with exchange rate policy, as part of an overall macroeconomic policy
package, and that in many countries capital flows are more important
in this respect than current flows; capital controls can be used to
manipulate exchange rates or to delay needed external adjustment; and
a country's capital account policy creates externalities for other
countries. Capital account policy is therefore of central importance
to surveillance.
- The IMF could sharpen its advice on capital account issues,
based on solid analysis of the particular situation and risks facing
specific countries. Given the limited evidence that exists in the
literature on the benefits or costs of capital account liberalization
in the abstract, the IMF's approach to any capital account issue must
necessarily be based on an analysis of each case. For example, if a
capital control is involved, the IMF must ask in the context of a specific
country what objectives the control is designed to achieve; if it is
accomplishing them; and whether there are more effective or less distortionary
ways of achieving the same objectives. Such assessments need to be
set in an overall consideration of the macroeconomic policy framework
and whether controls are being used as a substitute for, or to seek
to delay, necessary changes in such policies. The evaluation indicates
that this is already done in some, but not all, cases. If a capital
control measure is judged useful to stem capital flight under certain
circumstances, the IMF should ask what supporting policies are needed
to make it more effective or less distortionary (for example, setting
up a system of monitoring external transactions). In terms of providing
advice on capital account liberalization, just to spell out all the
risks inherent in opening the capital account is of limited usefulness
to countries seeking IMF advice. To assist the authorities decide when
and how to open the capital account, the IMF should provide some quantitative
gauge of the benefits, costs, and risks (and, indeed, practicality)
of moving at different speeds. Admittedly, this is not an easy task.
Drawing on the well-established literature on welfare economics, the
IMF must ask such questions as: What distortions are being created
when one market is liberalized but not another? What is the nature
of risks being borne by residents when capital account transactions
are liberalized only for nonresidents? And what are the costs to the
economy (in terms of investment flows) of allowing equity inflows but
not debt inflows?
- The Executive Board could issue a statement clarifying the
common elements of agreement on capital account liberalization. At
present, there remains considerable uncertainty among many staff members
on what policy advice to provide to individual countries. This has
led to hesitancy on the part of some within the staff to raise capital
account issues with country authorities. The Executive Board could
provide clear guidance to staff on what the IMF's official position
is. This is not to say that the Executive Board must come up with a
definitive statement on all aspects of pace and sequencing. Given the
lack of full consensus, one should not expect such a definitive view
from the Board. However, Board guidance on what are the minimum common
elements on which there is broad, if not universal, agreement would
be useful to the staff and member countries. Although the details are
for the Board to decide, such a statement might include some or all
of the following elements: (1) that in a first-best world there
would be no need for controls over capital movements (though financial
markets may not always operate accordingly); (2) that controls
should not be used as a substitute for adjusting macroeconomic or structural
policies; (3) a broad (as opposed to unnecessarily complex)
framework of sequencing based on the consensus in the literature on
the order of economic reforms; (4) the importance of taking country-specific
circumstances into account; and (5) that risks can never be totally
eliminated, so they should not be used as a reason for permanently
delaying liberalization.
Recommendation 2: The IMF's analysis and surveillance should give
greater attention to the supply-side factors of international capital
flows and what can be done to minimize the volatility of capital movements. The
IMF's policy advice on managing capital flows has so far focused to
a considerable extent on what recipient countries should do. While
this is important, it is not the whole story. As discussed in the evaluation
report, the IMF's recent analyses have given greater attention to supply-side
factors, including the dynamics of boom-and-bust cycles in emerging
market financing. The IMF has also established an International Capital
Markets Department (ICM) as part of an effort to better understand
global financial markets; it participates actively in the work of the
Financial Stability Forum, which was established to monitor potential
vulnerabilities in global financial markets; and it has proposed a
Sovereign Debt Restructuring Mechanism (SDRM), encouraged the use of
collective action clauses (CACs), and has attempted to place limitations
on countries' access to IMF resources in a crisis, in an effort to
reduce the perceived moral hazard that may have led capital markets
to pay insufficient attention to the risks of investing in developing
countries and contributed to the boom-and-bust cycles of capital movements.
These are important and welcome initiatives, but the IMF has not yet
fully addressed issues of what, if anything, can be done to minimize
the volatility of capital flows by operating on the supply sideas
yet, little attention seems to be paid to supply-side risks and potential
mitigating actions in the industrial countries that are home to the
major global financial markets. The IMF could usefully provide more
input into advanced country financial supervision and other financial
market policy issues globally. Are current global supervision guidelines
designed to help create stability? What if any action could be taken
on the supply side to reduce cyclicality and herd behavior? Admittedly,
this is a difficult topic on which little professional consensus exists.
Yet, this is an area where a significant debate has taken place in
the academic and policymaking communities and to which the IMF could
contribute further. Indeed, one of the broad themes identified as potential
priorities for the IMF's research program over the medium termon institutions
and contractual mechanisms that can help protect countries from external
volatilitygoes some way in this direction, but should not focus only
on policies in countries that are recipients of capital inflows.
1 The report was prepared by a team headed
by Shinji Takagi and including Jeffrey Allen Chelsky, Edna Armendariz,
Misa Takebe, and Halim Kucur. It also benefited from substantive contributions
from Rawi Abdelal, Masahiro Kawai, David Peretz, and Jai Won Ryou. The
report was approved by David Goldsbrough, Acting Director of the Independent
Evaluation Office (IEO).
|